Knowledge

Generalised cost

Source 📝

130: 513:) is considered to be irrelevant for the purposes of the exercise (for example, when comparing different journey options through a public transport network when fares are constant), there is no need to convert the generalised cost to a currency value - instead, it can be left in units of time, as long as all time is equivalent (for example, if all time is converted to in-vehicle time). These units of time may be referred to as 33: 497:
An alternative approach to applying different values of time to each part of the journey is to apply a weighting to time spent on each different part of the journey which quantifies the level of dislike a traveller has for time spent on that bit of the journey relative to time spent in-vehicle. For
489:
Typically, although travellers "dislike" all time spent travelling, they dislike walking and waiting parts of the journey more than in-vehicle journey time, and thus would be willing to pay more to avoid them. This results in a higher value of time for those parts of the journey than the main
498:
example, if a traveller considers 10 minutes' walk to be "as bad" as 12 minutes in a vehicle, then each minute of walking time is equivalent to 1.2 minutes of in-vehicle time. In this manner, all parts of the journey can be converted into their equivalent in-vehicle time.
339:
system, every traveller imposes a small delay on every other traveller, increasing the journey time for all travellers. The generalised cost function can be expanded to reflect this
613: 405: 324: 246: 148:
and non-monetary costs of a journey. It is sometimes used as a basis for judgements of transit accessibility and equitable distribution of public transit resources.
465:
It has been observed that travellers prefer time spent on some parts of their journey over time spent on others. A typical journey can be divided into four parts:
455: 413:
refers to the opportunity cost of the additional journey time a traveller experiences because of congestion. In transport economic models, the parameter
272:
is a measure of road standard or public transport service level, both of which are related to capacity). When the free-flow journey time is known,
424:
For example, if the travel time on a particular stretch of road increases by 10 minutes for every 1000 vehicles per hour that use the road, if
501:
Once the equivalent in-vehicle time for the whole journey is calculated, this can be converted to a monetary value as described earlier.
116: 50: 97: 69: 54: 650: 76: 655: 194: 129: 83: 182:
Non-monetary costs refer to the time spent undertaking the journey. Time is converted to a money value using a
482:(All of these apply to public transport journeys; the wait for the vehicle does not generally apply to car or 265: 65: 43: 604:
El-Geneidy, Ahmed; Levinson, David; Diab, Ehab; Boisjoly, Genevieve; Verbich, David; Loong, Charis (2016).
152: 193:
theory, and so demand for journeys can be related to the generalised cost of those journeys using the
348: 137: 606:"The cost of equity: Assessing transit accessibility and social disparity using total travel cost" 605: 586: 551: 428:
were measured in thousands of vehicles per hour, we would consider the congestion function to be
336: 291: 210: 190: 186:
figure, which usually varies according to the traveller's income and the purpose of the trip.
90: 626: 578: 543: 281: 160: 494:
mentioned earlier can therefore be considered to consist of differing sets of valued time.
421:
is a measure of capacity (which is relevant when considering possible capacity expansion).
431: 260:
refers to the non-monetary (time) costs of an uncongested journey. This is a function of
644: 555: 183: 168: 172: 197:. Supply is equivalent to capacity (and, for roads, road quality) on the network. 32: 17: 630: 622: 145: 569:
Cesario, Frank J (1976). "Value of Time in Recreation Benefit Studies".
486:
journeys, and for walk-only journeys, there is no division into parts.)
205:
In a basic form, the generalised cost (g) is composed of the following:
590: 547: 534:
Bruzelius, Nils A (1981). "Microeconomic theory and generalised cost".
483: 582: 128: 164: 156: 189:
The generalised cost is equivalent to the price of the good in
176: 26: 254:
refers to the monetary (out-of-pocket) costs of the journey.
276:
can be calculated as the product of the journey time (
434: 351: 294: 213: 614:
Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice
57:. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. 449: 399: 318: 240: 490:in-vehicle part of the journey. The function 8: 433: 350: 293: 212: 117:Learn how and when to remove this message 526: 509:If the monetary cost of the journey ( 7: 280:) in uncongested conditions and the 55:adding citations to reliable sources 25: 461:Weighting different types of time 31: 400:{\displaystyle g=p+u(w)+v(q,w)} 42:needs additional citations for 394: 382: 373: 367: 304: 298: 235: 229: 1: 319:{\displaystyle u(w)=\tau t} 672: 195:price elasticity of demand 631:10.1016/j.tra.2016.07.003 284:of the traveller's time ( 173:toll or congestion charge 163:journey, or the costs of 155:") costs might include a 266:transport economic model 241:{\displaystyle g=p+u(w)} 171:and any parking charge, 478:Walk to the destination 451: 401: 320: 242: 133: 452: 402: 321: 243: 132: 472:Wait for the vehicle 469:Walk from the origin 450:{\displaystyle v=2q} 432: 409:The additional term 349: 331:Congestible networks 292: 211: 51:improve this article 651:Transport economics 475:Ride in the vehicle 138:transport economics 548:10.1007/BF00148460 447: 417:is the demand and 397: 316: 238: 144:is the sum of the 134: 66:"Generalised cost" 656:Freight transport 191:supply and demand 127: 126: 119: 101: 16:(Redirected from 663: 635: 634: 610: 601: 595: 594: 566: 560: 559: 531: 515:generalised time 505:Generalised time 456: 454: 453: 448: 406: 404: 403: 398: 341:congestion delay 325: 323: 322: 317: 282:opportunity cost 247: 245: 244: 239: 161:public transport 142:generalised cost 122: 115: 111: 108: 102: 100: 59: 35: 27: 21: 18:Generalized cost 671: 670: 666: 665: 664: 662: 661: 660: 641: 640: 639: 638: 608: 603: 602: 598: 583:10.2307/3144984 568: 567: 563: 533: 532: 528: 523: 507: 463: 430: 429: 347: 346: 333: 290: 289: 209: 208: 203: 123: 112: 106: 103: 60: 58: 48: 36: 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 669: 667: 659: 658: 653: 643: 642: 637: 636: 596: 571:Land Economics 561: 542:(3): 233–245. 536:Transportation 525: 524: 522: 519: 506: 503: 480: 479: 476: 473: 470: 462: 459: 446: 443: 440: 437: 396: 393: 390: 387: 384: 381: 378: 375: 372: 369: 366: 363: 360: 357: 354: 332: 329: 328: 327: 315: 312: 309: 306: 303: 300: 297: 255: 237: 234: 231: 228: 225: 222: 219: 216: 202: 199: 151:Monetary (or " 125: 124: 39: 37: 30: 24: 14: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 668: 657: 654: 652: 649: 648: 646: 632: 628: 624: 620: 616: 615: 607: 600: 597: 592: 588: 584: 580: 576: 572: 565: 562: 557: 553: 549: 545: 541: 537: 530: 527: 520: 518: 516: 512: 504: 502: 499: 495: 493: 487: 485: 477: 474: 471: 468: 467: 466: 460: 458: 444: 441: 438: 435: 427: 422: 420: 416: 412: 407: 391: 388: 385: 379: 376: 370: 364: 361: 358: 355: 352: 344: 342: 338: 330: 313: 310: 307: 301: 295: 287: 283: 279: 275: 271: 267: 263: 259: 256: 253: 250: 249: 248: 232: 226: 223: 220: 217: 214: 206: 200: 198: 196: 192: 187: 185: 184:value of time 180: 178: 174: 170: 169:wear and tear 166: 162: 158: 154: 153:out-of-pocket 149: 147: 143: 139: 131: 121: 118: 110: 99: 96: 92: 89: 85: 82: 78: 75: 71: 68: –  67: 63: 62:Find sources: 56: 52: 46: 45: 40:This article 38: 34: 29: 28: 19: 618: 612: 599: 577:(1): 32–41. 574: 570: 564: 539: 535: 529: 514: 510: 508: 500: 496: 491: 488: 481: 464: 425: 423: 418: 414: 410: 408: 345: 340: 334: 285: 277: 273: 269: 261: 257: 251: 207: 204: 188: 181: 150: 141: 135: 113: 104: 94: 87: 80: 73: 61: 49:Please help 44:verification 41: 625:: 302–316. 337:congestible 288:), so that 107:August 2018 645:Categories 521:References 201:Basic form 77:newspapers 556:153355844 311:τ 179:journey. 623:Elsevier 264:(in the 146:monetary 591:3144984 484:bicycle 91:scholar 589:  554:  411:v(q,w) 140:, the 93:  86:  79:  72:  64:  609:(PDF) 587:JSTOR 552:S2CID 335:In a 175:on a 159:on a 98:JSTOR 84:books 492:u(w) 274:u(w) 258:u(w) 165:fuel 157:fare 70:news 627:doi 579:doi 544:doi 177:car 136:In 53:by 647:: 621:. 619:91 617:. 611:. 585:. 575:52 573:. 550:. 540:10 538:. 517:. 457:. 343:. 268:, 167:, 633:. 629:: 593:. 581:: 558:. 546:: 511:p 445:q 442:2 439:= 436:v 426:q 419:w 415:q 395:) 392:w 389:, 386:q 383:( 380:v 377:+ 374:) 371:w 368:( 365:u 362:+ 359:p 356:= 353:g 326:. 314:t 308:= 305:) 302:w 299:( 296:u 286:τ 278:t 270:w 262:w 252:p 236:) 233:w 230:( 227:u 224:+ 221:p 218:= 215:g 120:) 114:( 109:) 105:( 95:· 88:· 81:· 74:· 47:. 20:)

Index

Generalized cost

verification
improve this article
adding citations to reliable sources
"Generalised cost"
news
newspapers
books
scholar
JSTOR
Learn how and when to remove this message

transport economics
monetary
out-of-pocket
fare
public transport
fuel
wear and tear
toll or congestion charge
car
value of time
supply and demand
price elasticity of demand
transport economic model
opportunity cost
congestible
bicycle
doi

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.