Knowledge (XXG)

Heckscher–Ohlin model

Source 📝

224:
Economics. The H-O model advances international trade theory by introducing the concept of factor endowments within a country as well as the underlying causes for differences in comparative costs between countries, while assuming countries will have identical production technologies. The H-O framework finds that countries have differing comparative costs even though they have the same production technologies due to differences in factors of production, such as the geographical abundance of natural resources or population size. Furthermore, what the H-O model concludes is that traded commodities are essentially bundles of factors (land, labor, and capital) and therefore the international trade of commodities is indirect factor arbitrage (Leamer 1995).The H-O model more accurately describes international trade patterns in modern times (post WWII) due to the increased ability of transferring knowledge/ production technologies between countries, mainly focusing on factorial differences such as labor force and resource allocation as to why countries trade with each other. The Ricardian model of
215:
factor when a cheaper factor is more abundant. The theory predicts that nations will export the goods that make the most of the factors that are abundant in their soil and will import those that are made with scarce factors. Thus, this theory aims to explain the scheme of international trade that we observe in the world economy. Ohlin and Heckscher's theory advocates that the pattern of international trade is determined by differences in factor endowments rather than by differences in productivity. The endowments are relative and not absolute. One nation may have more land and workers than another but be relatively abundant in one of two factors. For example; The United States is a leading exporter of agricultural products, which reflects its great abundance of arable land, and on the other hand, China excels in the export of goods made with cheap labor such as textiles or shoes. This demonstrates why the United States has been a large importer of these Chinese products since it does not abound in cheap labor.
1536:
should say as important as labor. By the help of machines and apparatuses, the human being got a tremendous production capability. These machines, apparatuses and tools are classified as capital, or more precisely as durable capital, for one uses these items for many years. Their quantity is not changed at once. But the capital is not an endowment given by the nature. It is composed of goods manufactured in the production and often imported from foreign countries. In this sense, capital is internationally mobile and the result of past economic activity. The concept of capital as natural endowment distorts the real role of capital. Capital is a production power accumulated by the past investment.
1196:
equations holds. The results obtained by Bowen, Leamer and Sveiskaus (1987) were disastrous. They examined the cases of 12 factors and 27 countries for the year 1967. They found that the two sides of the equations had the same sign only for 61% of 324 cases. For the year 1983, the result was more disastrous. Both sides had the same sign only for 148 cases out of 297 cases (or the rate of correct predictions was 49.8%). The results of Bowen, Leamer, and Sveiskaus (1987) mean that the Heckscher–Ohlin–Vanek (HOV) theory has no predictive power concerning the direction of trade.
1527:
countries is the main concern for the development of poor countries. The standard Heckscher–Ohlin model ignores all these vital factors when one wants to consider development of less developed countries in the international context. Even between developed countries, technology differs from industry to industry and firm to firm base. Indeed, this is the very basis of the competition between firms, inside the country and across the country. See the New Trade Theory in this article below.
31: 1603:
gives focus on the diversity of enterprises. It is a fact that some enterprises engage in export and some that do not. Some enterprises invest directly in the foreign country in order to produce and sell in that country. Some other enterprises engage only in export. Why does this kind of differences occur? New Trade Theory tries to find out the reasons of these well observed facts.
1669: 1480:
theory claims that the state of factor endowments of each country (or each region) determines the production of each country (respectively of each region) but Bernstein and Weinstein found that the factor endowments have little predictive power. The factor-endowments-driven model (FED model) has errors much greater than the HOV model.
1535:
In the modern production system, machines and apparatuses play an important role. What is referred to as capital is nothing other than these machines and apparatuses, together with materials and intermediate products consumed in the production process. Capital is the most important of factors, or one
1459:
Initially, when the countries are not trading: The price of the capital-intensive good in the capital-abundant country will be bid down relative to the price of the good in the other country, the price of the labor-intensive good in the labor-abundant country will be bid down relative to the price of
891:
is much more mobile than labor, so import of capital to a country almost certainly shifts the relative factor-abundances in favor of capital. The magnification effect says that a 10% increase in national capital may lead to a redistribution of labor amounting to a fifth of the entire economy (towards
775:
where price is equal to the costs of factors of production. This theorem is useful in explaining the effects of immigration, emigration, and foreign capital investment. However, Rybczynski suggests that a fixed quantity of the two factors of production are required. This could be expanded to consider
214:
The comparative advantage is due to the fact that nations have various factors of production, the endowment of factors is the number of resources such as land, labor, and capital that a country has. Countries are endowed with multiple factors which explains the difference in the costs of a particular
1653:
Ricardian theory is now extended in a general form to include not only labor, but also inputs of materials and intermediate goods. In this sense, it is much more general and plausible than the Heckscher–Ohlin model and escapes the logical problems such as capital as endowments, which is, in reality,
607:
It is further assumed that capital can shift easily into either technology, so that the industrial mix can change without adjustment costs between the two types of production. For instance, if the two industries are farming and fishing it is assumed that farms can be sold to pay for the construction
367:
In addition to natural advantages in the production of one sort of output over another (wine vs. rice, say) the infrastructure, education, culture, and "know-how" of countries differ so dramatically that the idea of identical technologies is a theoretical notion. Ohlin said that the H–O model was a
275:
The original H–O model assumed that the only difference between countries was the relative abundances of labour and capital. The original Heckscher–Ohlin model contained two countries, and had two commodities that could be produced. Since there are two (homogeneous) factors of production this model
355:
be done with the same level of capital and labour in either country. Actually, it would be inefficient to use the same balance in either country (because of the relative availability of either input factor) but, in principle this would be possible. Another way of saying this is that the per-capita
1602:
New Trade Theory analyses individual enterprises and plants in an international competitive situation. The classical trade theory—i.e., the Heckscher–Ohlin model—has no enterprises in mind. The new trade theory treats enterprises in an industry as identical entities. "New" New Trade Theory (NNTT)
1582:
From the middle of the 19th century to 1930s, giant flows of immigration took place from Europe to North America. It is estimated that more than 60 million people crossed the Atlantic Ocean. Some politicians worried about negative consequences of immigration, such as cultural conflicts. For those
1553:
is determined according to how abundant capital is. If capital is scarce, it has a high rate of profit. If it is abundant, the profit rate is low. Therefore, before the profit rate is determined, the amount of capital is not measured - but we need to know the amount of capital to know the rate of
1517:
Heckscher–Ohlin theory is badly adapted to the analyze south–north trade problems. The assumptions of H–O are unrealistic with respect to north–south trade. Income differences between North and South is the concern that third world cares most. The factor price equalization theorem has not shown a
1195:
the world total endowment vector of factors. For many countries and many factors, it is possible to estimate the left hand sides and right hand sides independently. To put it another way, the left hand side tells the direction of factor service trade. Thus it is possible to ask how this system of
1479:
A common understanding exists that in the national level HOV model fits well. In fact, Davis and others found that HOV model fitted extremely well with the regional data of Japan. Even when the HOV formula fits well, it does not mean that Heckscher–Ohlin theory is valid. Indeed, Heckscher–Ohlin
755:
Exports of a capital-abundant country come from capital-intensive industries, and labour-abundant countries import such goods, exporting labour-intensive goods in return. Competitive pressures within the H–O model produce this prediction fairly straightforwardly. Conveniently, this is an easily
396:
The assumption of constant returns to scale CRS is useful because it exhibits a diminishing returns in a factor. Under constant returns to scale, doubling both capital and labor leads to a doubling of the output. Since outputs are increasing in both factors of production, doubling capital while
376:
In a simple model, both countries produce two commodities. Each commodity in turn is made using two factors of production. The production of each commodity requires input from both factors of production—capital (K) and labor (L). The technologies of each commodity is assumed to exhibit constant
206:
For example, a country where capital and land are abundant but labor is scarce has a comparative advantage in goods that require lots of capital and land, but little labor — such as grains. If capital and land are abundant, their prices are low. As they are the main factors in the production of
1548:
or a conveyor belt. Capital goods can be highly specialised and have no use beyond the precise operation they are intended for. Despite this, capital in the Heckscher–Ohlin model is assumed to be homogeneous and transferable to any form if necessary. This assumption not only conflicts with the
1526:
The standard Heckscher–Ohlin model assumes that the production functions are identical for all countries concerned. This means that all countries are in the same level of production and have the same technology, yet this is highly unrealistic. Technological gap between developed and developing
678:
Like capital, labor movements are not permitted in the Heckscher–Ohlin world, since this would drive an equalization of relative abundances of the two production factors, just as in the case of capital immobility. This condition is more defensible as a description of the modern world than the
228:
has trade ultimately motivated by differences in labour productivity using different "technologies". Heckscher and Ohlin did not require production technology to vary between countries, so (in the interests of simplicity) the "H–O model has identical production technology everywhere". Ricardo
363:
Countries have natural advantages in the production of various commodities in relation to one another, so this is an "unrealistic" simplification designed to highlight the effect of variable factors. This meant that the original H–O model produced an alternative explanation for free trade to
223:
While still building on traditional models such as the Ricardian framework, the mid 1900s bring forth innovation in international trade theory with the introduction of the Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) model, developed by Swedish economists Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin from the Stockholm School of
1219:(1980, chp.4) proposed the integrated world equilibrium (IWE) diagram to illustrate the equilibrium with mobile factors: world prices will remain unchanged when factor endowments are redistributed within the factor price equalization (FPE) set. . Much literature confirmed this result fully. 260:
first explained the theory in a book published in 1933. Ohlin wrote the book alone, but he credited Heckscher as co-developer of the model because of his earlier work on the problem, and because many of the ideas in the final model came from Ohlin's doctoral thesis, supervised by Heckscher.
1455:
The critical assumption of the Heckscher–Ohlin model is that the two countries are identical, except for the difference in resource endowments. This also implies that the aggregate preferences are the same. The relative abundance in capital leads the capital-abundant country to produce the
1549:
observable diversity and specificity of the capital stock, but also contains a further flaw, namely in how the amount of capital is measured. Usually, this would be done through the price system, which depends on the profit rate. However, In the Heckscher–Ohlin model, the
591:) have equal value. The more capital-abundant country may gain by developing its fishing fleet at the expense of its arable farms. Conversely, the workers available in the relatively labor-abundant country can be employed relatively more efficiently in arable farming. 959:
Various attempts in the 1960s and 1970s have been made to "solve" the Leontief paradox and save the Heckscher–Ohlin model from failing. From the 1980s a new series of statistical tests had been tried. The new tests depended on Vanek's formula. It takes a simple form
1227:(1985, p.23-24) further used equal-trade-volume lines to illustrate trade equilibrium and the trade basics in the IWE diagram. Guo (2023) introduced a Dixit-Norman constant and used the equal trade volume line to obtain the general trade equilibrium by 1438:
The factor-price equalization theorem about the relationship between factor prices and factor supplies is empty. This is an important supplement to show the supply-demand relationship between factor prices and factor supplies. The equilibrium links
1433: 1504:
However, if labor is separated into two distinct factors, skilled labor and unskilled labor, the Heckscher–Ohlin theorem is more accurate. The U.S. tends to export skilled-labor-intensive goods, and tends to import unskilled-labor-intensive goods.
306:
The model has been extended since the 1930s by many economists. These developments did not change the fundamental role of variable factor proportions in driving international trade, but added to the model various real-world considerations (such as
883:
Assuming fixed capital, population growth dilutes the scarcity of labor in relation to capital. If the population growth outpaces the growth in capital by 10% this may translate into a 20% shift in the balance of employment to the labor-intensive
1513:
The factor equalization theorem (FET) applies only to the most advanced countries. The average wage in Japan was once as big as 70 times the wage in Vietnam. These wage discrepancies are not normally in the scope of the H–O model analysis.
923:
estimates have shown the model to perform poorly, however, and adjustments have been suggested, most importantly the assumption that technology is not the same everywhere. This change would mean abandoning the pure H–O model.
1211:. He verbally stated an idea that, assuming the borders between the two countries were redrawn and thereby production and factors "redistributed" across the borders in the two economies, the main variables would remain unchanged . 1569:
Standard Heckscher–Ohlin theory assumes the same production function for all countries. This implies that all firms are identical. The theoretical consequence is that there is no room for firms in the H–O model. By contrast, the
342:
The original, 2×2×2 model was derived with restrictive assumptions, partly for the sake of mathematical simplicity. Some of these have been relaxed for the sake of development. These assumptions and developments are listed here.
170:
of a trading region. The model essentially says that countries export the products which use their relatively abundant and cheap factors of production, and import the products which use the countries' relatively scarce factors.
770:
When the amount of one factor of production increases, the production of the good that uses that particular production factor intensively increases relative to the increase in the factor of production, as the H–O model assumes
911:
Heckscher and Ohlin considered the Factor-Price Equalization theorem an econometric success because the large volume of international trade in the late 19th and early 20th centuries coincided with the convergence of commodity
634:
factor abundance (in relation to mobile capital) because the labour/capital ratio would be identical everywhere. (A large country would receive twice as much investment as a small one, for instance, maximizing capitalist's
603:
argument, this is assumed to happen without cost. If the two production technologies are the arable industry and the fishing industry it is assumed that farmers can shift to work as fishermen with no cost and vice versa.
1475:
testing of H–O model theorems". Daniel Trefler and Susan Chun Zhu summarizes their paper that "It is hard to believe that factor endowments theory could offer an adequate explanation of international trade patterns".
1558:, which ultimately concluded that the concept of homogeneous capital was untenable. This is a serious blow to Heckscher-Ohlin theory, which has not been able to refute this theoretical flaw at the heart of the model. 1500:
in 1953, found that the U.S. (the most capital-abundant country in the world by any criterion) exported labor-intensive commodities and imported capital-intensive commodities, contrary to the Heckscher–Ohlin theory.
824:
trade makes factor prices converge along with traded goods prices. The FPE theorem is the most significant conclusion of the H–O model, but also has found the least agreement with the economic evidence. Neither the
1483:
Unemployment is the vital question in any trade conflict. Heckscher–Ohlin theory excludes unemployment by the very formulation of the model, in which all factors (including labour) are employed in the production.
1023: 942:
of the H–O model found that the United States, despite having a relative abundance of capital, tended to export labor-intensive goods and import capital-intensive goods. This problem became known as the
695:(capital was immobile, but repatriation of foreign sales was costless). It was also free of transportation costs between the countries, or any other savings that would favor procuring a local supply. 717:
research since the 1950s have shown that the local prices of goods tend to correlate with incomes when both are converted at money prices (though this is less true with traded commodities). See:
642:
As capital controls are reduced, the modern world has begun to look a lot less like the world modelled by Heckscher and Ohlin. It has been argued that capital mobility undermines the case for
790:
Relative changes in output goods prices drive the relative prices of the factors used to produce them. If the world price of capital-intensive goods increases, it increases the relative
551: 482: 249:
the model's equations. The decision that capital owners are faced with is between investments in differing production technologies; the H–O model assumes capital is privately held.
1233: 1104: 1055: 1657:
As the theory permits different production processes to coexist in an industry of a country, the Ricardo–Sraffa theory can give a theoretical bases for the New Trade Theory.
880:) predicts a larger proportionate shift in output-quantity than in the corresponding endowment factor shift that induced it. This has implications to both labor and capital: 849:
rents and wages. The Magnification effect on prices considers the effect of output-goods price-changes on the real return to capital and labor. This is done by dividing the
1193: 237:
at various stages of growth, with no reason to trade with each other). The H–O model removed technology variations but introduced variable capital endowments, recreating
116: 76: 619:
The basic Heckscher–Ohlin model depends upon the relative availability of capital and labor differing internationally, but if capital can be freely invested anywhere,
1151: 389:. For example, if both capital and labor inputs are doubled, output of the commodities is doubled. In other terms the production function of both commodities is " 211:
goods, on the other hand, are very expensive to produce since labor is scarce and its price is high. Therefore, the country is better off importing those goods.
1171: 1124: 1075: 203:
of goods is determined by input costs. Goods that require locally abundant inputs are cheaper to produce than those goods that require locally scarce inputs.
245:
and goods requiring different factor "proportions", Ricardo's comparative advantage emerges as a profit-maximizing solution of capitalist's choices from
1583:
politicians, the Heckscher-Ohlin theory of Trade provided a good reason “in support of both restrictions on labor migration and free trade in goods”.
279:
The model has "variable factor proportions" between countries—highly developed countries have a comparatively high capital-to-labor ratio compared to
1987:; Bradford, S. D.; Shimpo, K. (1997), "Using International and Japanese Regional Data to Determine When the Factor Abundance Theory of Trade Works", 241:
the inter-country variation of labour productivity that Ricardo had imposed exogenously. With international variations in the capital endowment like
233:(labour) and would not have been able to produce comparative advantage without technological differences between countries (all nations would become 2013:
Bernstein, J. R. & Weinstein, D. E. (2002), "Do endowments predict the location of production?: Evidence from national and international data",
397:
holding labor constant leads to less than doubling of an output. Diminishing returns to capital and diminishing returns to labor are crucial to the
1639:
The gravity model of international trade predicts bilateral trade flows based on the economic sizes of two nations, and the distance between them.
1463:
As a result: the capital-abundant country will export the capital-intensive good, the labor-abundant country will export the labor-intensive good.
1460:
the good in the other country. Once trade is allowed, profit-seeking firms move their products to the markets that have (temporary) higher prices.
2446: 1912:
Helpman, E. & Krugman, P. R. (1985). Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Chapter I - Preliminaries. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.
892:
capital-intensive, high-tech production). Notably, employment patterns in very poor countries can be dramatically affected by a small amount of
2316:"A New Construction of Ricardian Trade Theory—A Many-country, Many-commodity Case with Intermediate Goods and Choice of Production Techniques" 798:
rate (the return on capital as against the return to labor). Also, if the price of labor-intensive goods increases, it increases the relative
2387: 2364: 2165: 2138: 1772: 850: 846: 2421: 330:, so that variations of the model are sometimes called the Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelson model (HOS) or the Heckscher–Ohlin–Vanek model in the 119: 966: 951:, suggests that goods are traded based on similar demand rather than differences in supply side factors (i.e., H–O's factor endowments). 2441: 947:. Alternative trade models and various explanations for the paradox have emerged as a result of the paradox. One such trade model, the 364:
Ricardo's, rather than a complementary one; in reality, both effects may occur due to differences in technology and factor abundances.
1725: 238: 2412: 2461: 2299: 1614:
measures to build up a huge industrial base in certain industries would then allow those sectors to dominate the world market via a
1444: 741:
The results of this work has been the formulation of certain named conclusions arising from the assumptions inherent in the model.
2156:
Stewart, Frances (1989), "Recent Theories of International Trade: Some Implications for the South", in Kierzkowski, Henryk (ed.),
1847:
Bowen, Harry P.; Leamer, Edward E. & Sveiskaus, Leo (1987), "Multicountry, Multifactor Tests of the Factor Abundance Theory",
666:(FDI) is permitted between countries, or foreigners are permitted to invest in the commercial operations of a country through a 2456: 1471:
The original Heckscher–Ohlin model and extended model such as the Vanek model performs poorly, as it is shown in the section "
1715: 2062:
Wassily, Leontief (September 28, 1953). "Domestic Production and Foreign Trade; The American Capital Position Re-Examined".
1735: 785: 398: 1683: 1555: 155: 1688: 869:(because increased trade makes the price index fall by less than the drop in returns to the scarce-factor induced by the 599:
Within countries, capital and labor can be reinvested and reemployed to produce different outputs. Similar to Ricardo's
750: 2471: 2180:
Cohen, Avi J. & Harcourt, Geoffrey C. (2003), "Whatever Happened to the Cambridge Capital Theory Controversies?",
409:
The CRS production functions must differ to make trade worthwhile in this model. For instance if the functions are
283:. This makes the developed country capital-abundant relative to the developing country, and the developing nation 2451: 1903:
Dixit, A. & Norman, V. (1980) Theory of International Trade, Cambridge, England, Cambridge University Press.
893: 815: 663: 267:
itself was verbose, rather than being pared down to the mathematical, and appealed because of its new insights.
2252:
Greenaway, David & Kneller, Richard (2007), "Firm heterogeneity, exporting and foreign direct investment",
1949:
Trefler, Daniel & Zhu, Susan Chun (2000), "Beyond the Algebra of Explanation: HOV for the Technology Age",
1849: 489: 420: 2466: 1440: 729:
Neither labor nor capital has the power to affect prices or factor rates by constraining supply; a state of
703: 368:
long-run model, and that the conditions of industrial production are "everywhere the same" in the long run.
331: 78:): no trade, individual production equals consumption. Trade equilibrium: both countries consume the same ( 2222: 1710: 1634: 1428:{\displaystyle {\frac {wage(w^{*})}{rental(r^{*})}}={\frac {World\ Capital(K^{W})}{World\ Labor(L^{W})}}.} 647: 131: 710:
applies to both commodities, and consumers in either country pay exactly the same price for either good.
2420:
An econometric analysis of factor prices, commodity prices, and endowments in intercontinental trade by
1699: 1208: 600: 381:(CRS). CRS technologies implies that when inputs of both capital and labor is multiplied by a factor of 291: 225: 180: 167: 163: 2382:. Princeton Studies in International Finance. Vol. 77. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 34:
Basic situation: Two otherwise identical countries (A and B) have different initial factor endowments.
1080: 1031: 1720: 1694: 1622: 862: 636: 390: 280: 230: 2227: 284: 2211:(2003), "The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity", 939: 772: 730: 192: 143: 139: 1176: 311:) in the hopes of increasing the model's predictive power, or as a mathematical way of discussing 199:
for which the required factors of production are relatively abundant locally. This is because the
2335: 2271: 2071: 1996: 1984: 1966: 1858: 877: 833:
rates seem to consistently converge between trading partners at different levels of development.
765: 207:
grain, the price of grain is also low—and thus attractive for both local consumption and export.
200: 81: 41: 1764: 2089:
Milberg, William (24 May 2006). "The rhetoric of policy relevance in international economics".
857:, but took thirty years to develop completely because of the theoretical complexity involved. 2383: 2360: 2315: 2295: 2161: 2134: 2040: 1768: 1730: 948: 295: 195:) determine a country's comparative advantage. Countries have comparative advantages in those 188: 2289: 876:
The Magnification effect on production quantity-shifts induced by endowment changes (via the
713:
In Ohlin's day this assumption was a fairly neutral simplification, but economic changes and
410: 2327: 2261: 2232: 2189: 2106: 2098: 2022: 1958: 1931: 1886: 1877: 1830: 1803: 1674: 1607: 1597: 1571: 1497: 1493: 1216: 944: 933: 707: 692: 658: 580: 378: 196: 184: 1129: 1220: 323: 208: 2041:"Samuelson's Implicit Criticism against Sraffa and the Sraffians and Two Other Questions" 776:
factor substitution, in which case the increase in production is more than proportional.
623:(for investment) makes relative abundances identical throughout the world. Essentially, 360:
is the same in both countries in the same technology with identical amounts of capital.
2376: 1834: 1757: 1615: 1550: 1204: 1156: 1109: 1060: 671: 327: 319: 294:, using just two goods and two technologies to produce them. One technology would be a 242: 2026: 1922:
Guo, Baoping (2023). "Integrated Price-Trade Equilibrium by World Factor Endowments".
2435: 2339: 2275: 2266: 1648: 1611: 1212: 897: 312: 159: 147: 17: 2213: 1544:
Capital goods take different forms. It may take the form of a machine-tool such as
1224: 357: 257: 151: 2401:. Harvard Economic Studies. Vol. 39. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 579:
In this example, the marginal return to an extra unit of capital is higher in the
413:
technologies the parameters applied to the inputs must vary. An example would be:
2417: 2208: 1472: 1456:
capital-intensive good cheaper than the labor-abundant country, and vice versa.
920: 854: 821: 718: 714: 620: 30: 2194: 1935: 2102: 1705: 1664: 643: 624: 2236: 290:
With this single difference, Ohlin was able to discuss the new mechanism of
1691:– an international trade model with traded and non-traded economic sectors 1668: 1962: 1875:
Samuelson, Paul (1949). "International factor price equalization again".
699: 561: 351:
This assumption means that producing the same output of either commodity
234: 2331: 2131:
The fragmented world: competing perspectives on trade, money, and crisis
2111: 1702:– an international trade model with varying technology between countries 298:
industry, the other a labor-intensive business—see "assumptions" below.
2075: 2000: 1862: 826: 803: 791: 35: 2291:
The Fragmented World, Competing Perspective on Trade, Money and Crisis
1970: 2129:
Edwards, Chris (1985), "§2.3 The Fall of The Hecksher-Ohlin Theory",
706:
applies. Since there are no transaction costs or currency issues the
688: 308: 1890: 1018:{\displaystyle \mathbf {F_{C}} =\mathbf {V_{C}} -s_{C}\mathbf {V} } 1545: 888: 667: 630:
Differences in labour abundance would not produce a difference in
2424:
in 1999. It finds that 19th century trade patterns and economies
1561:
Usually by a system of prices. But prices depend on profit rate.
1554:
profit! This logical difficulty was the subject of the so-called
1518:
sign of realization, even for a long time lag of a half century.
372:
Production output is assumed to exhibit constant returns to scale
830: 799: 795: 687:
The 2x2x2 model originally placed no barriers to trade, had no
166:
by predicting patterns of commerce and production based on the
648:
Capital mobility and comparative advantage Free trade critique
2124: 2122: 1649:
David Ricardo § Ricardian theory of international trade
1606:
New Trade theorists challenge the assumption of diminishing
405:
The technologies used to produce the two commodities differ
2359:. Princeton: Princeton University Press. pp. 31–63. 2355:
Feenstra, Robert C. (2004). "The Heckscher–Ohlin Model".
2247: 2245: 679:
assumption that capital is confined to a single country.
1759:
The methodology of economics, or, How economists explain
627:
in capital provides a single worldwide investment pool.
611:
The theory by Avsar has offered much criticism to this.
865:
actually makes the locally-scarce factor of production
1817:
Vanek, J. (1968), "The Factor Proportions Theory: the
1057:
is the net trade of factor service vector for country
1236: 1179: 1159: 1132: 1112: 1083: 1063: 1034: 969: 492: 423: 84: 44: 1790:"The Heckscher-Ohlin Model in Theory and Practice." 1207:(1949) initialed the study of trade equilibrium in 347:
Both countries have identical production technology
2375: 1756: 1427: 1187: 1165: 1145: 1118: 1098: 1069: 1049: 1017: 545: 476: 122:; production and consumption points are divergent. 110: 70: 2357:Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence 2064:Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 276:is sometimes called the "2×2×2 model". 2428:be successfully modeled within an H-O framework. 2378:The Heckscher–Ohlin Model in Theory and Practice 2158:Monopolistic Competition and International Trade 2133:, London and New York: Methuen, pp. 29–40, 2418:The Heckscher–Ohlin Model Between 1400 and 2000 2320:Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review 907:Econometric testing of H–O model theorems 2151: 2149: 8: 2294:, London and New York: Methuen, p. 28, 2160:, Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 84–108, 702:, this does not affect the model in any way— 608:of fishing boats with no transaction costs. 385:, the output also multiplies by a factor of 2265: 2226: 2193: 2110: 1574:emphasizes that firms are heterogeneous. 1410: 1359: 1310: 1295: 1259: 1237: 1235: 1180: 1178: 1158: 1137: 1131: 1111: 1089: 1084: 1082: 1062: 1040: 1035: 1033: 1010: 1004: 990: 985: 975: 970: 968: 837:Implications of factor-proportion changes 532: 528: 523: 521: 510: 506: 501: 499: 491: 463: 459: 454: 452: 441: 437: 432: 430: 422: 102: 89: 83: 62: 49: 43: 2413:A precisely defined, two-goods H–O model 1924:International Advanced Economic Research 1106:the factor endowment vector for country 683:Commodity prices are the same everywhere 546:{\displaystyle F={{K}^{1/2}}{{L}^{1/2}}} 477:{\displaystyle A={{K}^{1/3}}{{L}^{2/3}}} 29: 1747: 810:Factor–price equalization theorem 1763:. Cambridge University Press. p.  1173:'s share of the world consumption and 568:is the output in fish production, and 287:in relation to the developed country. 27:Economic model for international trade 2399:Interregional and International Trade 576:are capital and labor in both cases. 265:Interregional and International Trade 7: 861:The Magnification effect shows that 698:If the two countries have separate 615:Factor immobility between countries 2015:Journal of International Economics 1835:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1968.tb00141.x 1726:List of international trade topics 25: 1445:factor price equalization theorem 2267:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02018.x 2182:Journal of Economic Perspectives 1667: 1181: 1099:{\displaystyle \mathbf {V_{C}} } 1090: 1086: 1050:{\displaystyle \mathbf {F_{C}} } 1041: 1037: 1011: 991: 987: 976: 972: 802:rate and decreases the relative 794:rate and decreases the relative 595:Factor mobility within countries 318:Notable contributions came from 2091:Journal of Economic Methodology 1556:Cambridge Capital Controversies 1200:General Price-Trade Equilibrium 938:In 1954 an econometric test by 871:Stolper–Samuelson theorem 843:Stolper–Samuelson theorem 786:Stolper–Samuelson theorem 780:Stolper–Samuelson theorem 120:Production–possibility frontier 118:), especially beyond their own 2447:International factor movements 1716:International factor movements 1689:Balassa–Samuelson effect 1587:Alternatives theories of trade 1416: 1403: 1365: 1352: 1301: 1288: 1265: 1252: 1: 2027:10.1016/S0022-1996(01)00108-8 1684:A rising tide lifts all boats 1522:Identical production function 751:Heckscher–Ohlin theorem 745:Heckscher–Ohlin theorem 156:Stockholm School of Economics 1610:, and some argue that using 1188:{\displaystyle \mathbf {V} } 896:, in this model. (See also: 725:Perfect internal competition 1643:Ricardo–Sraffa trade theory 1509:Factor equalization theorem 829:return to capital, nor the 179:Relative endowments of the 111:{\displaystyle C^{A}=C^{B}} 71:{\displaystyle A^{A},A^{B}} 2488: 2442:International trade theory 2374:Leamer, Edward E. (1995). 2195:10.1257/089533003321165010 1936:10.1007/s11294-023-09876-9 1646: 1632: 1595: 931: 813: 783: 763: 748: 583:, assuming units of fish ( 2103:10.1080/13501789600000017 2045:The Kyoto Economic Review 1736:Stolper–Samuelson theorem 916:factor prices worldwide. 816:Factor price equalization 664:Foreign direct investment 399:Stolper–Samuelson theorem 2462:1933 in economic history 1989:American Economic Review 1951:American Economic Review 1850:American Economic Review 653:Capital is mobile when: 2237:10.1111/1468-0262.00467 1804:"Heckscher-Ohlin Model" 1441:Heckscher-Ohlin theorem 704:purchasing power parity 338:Theoretical assumptions 332:neo-classical economics 219:Theoretical development 2457:Management cybernetics 2397:Ohlin, Bertil (1967). 2288:Edwards, Cris (1985), 1711:Gravity model of trade 1635:Gravity model of trade 1629:Gravity model of trade 1429: 1189: 1167: 1147: 1120: 1100: 1071: 1051: 1019: 547: 478: 142:mathematical model of 123: 112: 72: 2314:Shiozawa, Y. (2007), 2039:Shiozawa, Y. (2009), 1788:Leamer, Eric (1995). 1700:Comparative advantage 1430: 1209:Heckscher-Ohlin model 1190: 1168: 1148: 1146:{\displaystyle s_{C}} 1121: 1101: 1072: 1052: 1020: 887:In the modern world, 756:testable hypothesis. 601:comparative advantage 587:) and arable output ( 548: 479: 292:comparative advantage 226:comparative advantage 181:factors of production 175:Features of the model 164:comparative advantage 128:Heckscher–Ohlin model 113: 73: 33: 18:Heckscher-Ohlin model 2254:The Economic Journal 1963:10.1257/aer.90.2.145 1755:Blaug, Mark (1992). 1721:Intra-industry trade 1695:Beggar thy neighbour 1623:Intra-industry trade 1578:Political background 1531:Capital as endowment 1234: 1177: 1157: 1130: 1110: 1081: 1061: 1032: 967: 863:trade liberalization 637:return on investment 490: 421: 281:developing countries 253:Original publication 231:factor of production 229:considered a single 82: 42: 2332:10.14441/eier.3.141 1540:Homogeneous capital 940:Wassily W. Leontief 773:perfect competition 731:perfect competition 486:Fishing industry: 144:international trade 140:general equilibrium 2472:1930s in Stockholm 2260:(517): F134–F161, 1425: 1185: 1163: 1143: 1116: 1096: 1067: 1047: 1015: 878:Rybczynski theorem 766:Rybczynski theorem 760:Rybczynski theorem 657:There are limited 543: 474: 417:Arable industry: 124: 108: 68: 2389:978-0-88165-249-9 2366:978-0-691-11410-1 2167:978-0-19-828726-1 2140:978-0-416-73390-7 1774:978-0-521-43678-6 1731:Linder hypothesis 1565:No room for firms 1420: 1387: 1330: 1305: 1166:{\displaystyle c} 1119:{\displaystyle c} 1070:{\displaystyle c} 955:The Vanek formula 949:Linder hypothesis 693:exchange controls 659:exchange controls 560:is the output in 296:capital-intensive 16:(Redirected from 2479: 2452:Economics models 2402: 2393: 2381: 2370: 2343: 2342: 2311: 2305: 2304: 2285: 2279: 2278: 2269: 2249: 2240: 2239: 2230: 2221:(6): 1695–1725, 2205: 2199: 2198: 2197: 2177: 2171: 2170: 2153: 2144: 2143: 2126: 2117: 2116: 2114: 2086: 2080: 2079: 2059: 2053: 2052: 2036: 2030: 2029: 2010: 2004: 2003: 1985:Weinstein, D. E. 1980: 1974: 1973: 1946: 1940: 1939: 1919: 1913: 1910: 1904: 1901: 1895: 1894: 1885:(234): 181–197. 1878:Economic Journal 1872: 1866: 1865: 1844: 1838: 1837: 1814: 1808: 1807: 1800: 1794: 1793: 1785: 1779: 1778: 1762: 1752: 1677: 1675:Economics portal 1672: 1671: 1654:produced goods. 1608:returns to scale 1598:New Trade Theory 1592:New Trade Theory 1572:New Trade Theory 1498:Wassily Leontief 1494:Leontief paradox 1488:Leontief paradox 1467:predictive power 1434: 1432: 1431: 1426: 1421: 1419: 1415: 1414: 1385: 1368: 1364: 1363: 1328: 1311: 1306: 1304: 1300: 1299: 1268: 1264: 1263: 1238: 1217:Victor D. Norman 1194: 1192: 1191: 1186: 1184: 1172: 1170: 1169: 1164: 1152: 1150: 1149: 1144: 1142: 1141: 1125: 1123: 1122: 1117: 1105: 1103: 1102: 1097: 1095: 1094: 1093: 1076: 1074: 1073: 1068: 1056: 1054: 1053: 1048: 1046: 1045: 1044: 1024: 1022: 1021: 1016: 1014: 1009: 1008: 996: 995: 994: 981: 980: 979: 945:Leontief paradox 934:Leontief paradox 928:Leontief paradox 708:law of one price 581:fishing industry 552: 550: 549: 544: 542: 541: 540: 536: 527: 520: 519: 518: 514: 505: 483: 481: 480: 475: 473: 472: 471: 467: 458: 451: 450: 449: 445: 436: 379:returns to scale 315:policy options. 133: 117: 115: 114: 109: 107: 106: 94: 93: 77: 75: 74: 69: 67: 66: 54: 53: 21: 2487: 2486: 2482: 2481: 2480: 2478: 2477: 2476: 2432: 2431: 2409: 2396: 2390: 2373: 2367: 2354: 2351: 2349:Further reading 2346: 2313: 2312: 2308: 2302: 2287: 2286: 2282: 2251: 2250: 2243: 2228:10.1.1.563.6294 2207: 2206: 2202: 2179: 2178: 2174: 2168: 2155: 2154: 2147: 2141: 2128: 2127: 2120: 2088: 2087: 2083: 2061: 2060: 2056: 2038: 2037: 2033: 2012: 2011: 2007: 1982: 1981: 1977: 1948: 1947: 1943: 1921: 1920: 1916: 1911: 1907: 1902: 1898: 1874: 1873: 1869: 1846: 1845: 1841: 1821:-Factor Case", 1816: 1815: 1811: 1802: 1801: 1797: 1787: 1786: 1782: 1775: 1754: 1753: 1749: 1745: 1740: 1673: 1666: 1663: 1651: 1645: 1637: 1631: 1600: 1594: 1589: 1580: 1567: 1542: 1533: 1524: 1511: 1496:, presented by 1490: 1469: 1453: 1406: 1369: 1355: 1312: 1291: 1269: 1255: 1239: 1232: 1231: 1221:Elhanan Helpman 1202: 1175: 1174: 1155: 1154: 1133: 1128: 1127: 1108: 1107: 1085: 1079: 1078: 1059: 1058: 1036: 1030: 1029: 1000: 986: 971: 965: 964: 957: 936: 930: 909: 839: 818: 812: 788: 782: 768: 762: 753: 747: 739: 727: 685: 617: 597: 522: 500: 488: 487: 453: 431: 419: 418: 407: 374: 349: 340: 304: 273: 255: 221: 209:Labor-intensive 177: 160:David Ricardo's 158:. It builds on 146:, developed by 98: 85: 80: 79: 58: 45: 40: 39: 28: 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 2485: 2483: 2475: 2474: 2469: 2467:1933 in Sweden 2464: 2459: 2454: 2449: 2444: 2434: 2433: 2430: 2429: 2415: 2408: 2407:External links 2405: 2404: 2403: 2394: 2388: 2371: 2365: 2350: 2347: 2345: 2344: 2326:(2): 141–187, 2306: 2300: 2280: 2241: 2200: 2188:(1): 199–214, 2172: 2166: 2145: 2139: 2118: 2097:(2): 237–259. 2081: 2070:(4): 332–349. 2054: 2031: 2005: 1995:(3): 421–446, 1983:Davis, D. R.; 1975: 1957:(2): 145–149, 1941: 1930:(1): 193–205. 1914: 1905: 1896: 1891:10.1086/261911 1867: 1857:(5): 791–809, 1839: 1829:(4): 749–756, 1809: 1795: 1780: 1773: 1746: 1744: 1741: 1739: 1738: 1733: 1728: 1723: 1718: 1713: 1708: 1703: 1697: 1692: 1686: 1680: 1679: 1678: 1662: 1659: 1644: 1641: 1633:Main article: 1630: 1627: 1616:network effect 1596:Main article: 1593: 1590: 1588: 1585: 1579: 1576: 1566: 1563: 1551:rate of profit 1541: 1538: 1532: 1529: 1523: 1520: 1510: 1507: 1489: 1486: 1468: 1465: 1452: 1449: 1436: 1435: 1424: 1418: 1413: 1409: 1405: 1402: 1399: 1396: 1393: 1390: 1384: 1381: 1378: 1375: 1372: 1367: 1362: 1358: 1354: 1351: 1348: 1345: 1342: 1339: 1336: 1333: 1327: 1324: 1321: 1318: 1315: 1309: 1303: 1298: 1294: 1290: 1287: 1284: 1281: 1278: 1275: 1272: 1267: 1262: 1258: 1254: 1251: 1248: 1245: 1242: 1205:Paul Samuelson 1201: 1198: 1183: 1162: 1140: 1136: 1115: 1092: 1088: 1066: 1043: 1039: 1026: 1025: 1013: 1007: 1003: 999: 993: 989: 984: 978: 974: 956: 953: 932:Main article: 929: 926: 908: 905: 904: 903: 902: 901: 885: 874: 838: 835: 814:Main article: 811: 808: 784:Main article: 781: 778: 764:Main article: 761: 758: 749:Main article: 746: 743: 738: 735: 726: 723: 684: 681: 676: 675: 672:corporate bond 661: 616: 613: 596: 593: 554: 553: 539: 535: 531: 526: 517: 513: 509: 504: 498: 495: 484: 470: 466: 462: 457: 448: 444: 440: 435: 429: 426: 406: 403: 393:of degree 1". 373: 370: 348: 345: 339: 336: 328:Jaroslav Vanek 320:Paul Samuelson 303: 300: 285:labor-abundant 272: 269: 254: 251: 243:infrastructure 220: 217: 176: 173: 105: 101: 97: 92: 88: 65: 61: 57: 52: 48: 26: 24: 14: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 2484: 2473: 2470: 2468: 2465: 2463: 2460: 2458: 2455: 2453: 2450: 2448: 2445: 2443: 2440: 2439: 2437: 2427: 2423: 2419: 2416: 2414: 2411: 2410: 2406: 2400: 2395: 2391: 2385: 2380: 2379: 2372: 2368: 2362: 2358: 2353: 2352: 2348: 2341: 2337: 2333: 2329: 2325: 2321: 2317: 2310: 2307: 2303: 2301:9781317405979 2297: 2293: 2292: 2284: 2281: 2277: 2273: 2268: 2263: 2259: 2255: 2248: 2246: 2242: 2238: 2234: 2229: 2224: 2220: 2216: 2215: 2210: 2204: 2201: 2196: 2191: 2187: 2183: 2176: 2173: 2169: 2163: 2159: 2152: 2150: 2146: 2142: 2136: 2132: 2125: 2123: 2119: 2113: 2108: 2104: 2100: 2096: 2092: 2085: 2082: 2077: 2073: 2069: 2065: 2058: 2055: 2050: 2046: 2042: 2035: 2032: 2028: 2024: 2020: 2016: 2009: 2006: 2002: 1998: 1994: 1990: 1986: 1979: 1976: 1972: 1968: 1964: 1960: 1956: 1952: 1945: 1942: 1937: 1933: 1929: 1925: 1918: 1915: 1909: 1906: 1900: 1897: 1892: 1888: 1884: 1880: 1879: 1871: 1868: 1864: 1860: 1856: 1852: 1851: 1843: 1840: 1836: 1832: 1828: 1824: 1820: 1813: 1810: 1805: 1799: 1796: 1791: 1784: 1781: 1776: 1770: 1766: 1761: 1760: 1751: 1748: 1742: 1737: 1734: 1732: 1729: 1727: 1724: 1722: 1719: 1717: 1714: 1712: 1709: 1707: 1704: 1701: 1698: 1696: 1693: 1690: 1687: 1685: 1682: 1681: 1676: 1670: 1665: 1660: 1658: 1655: 1650: 1642: 1640: 1636: 1628: 1626: 1624: 1619: 1617: 1613: 1612:protectionist 1609: 1604: 1599: 1591: 1586: 1584: 1577: 1575: 1573: 1564: 1562: 1559: 1557: 1552: 1547: 1539: 1537: 1530: 1528: 1521: 1519: 1515: 1508: 1506: 1502: 1499: 1495: 1487: 1485: 1481: 1477: 1474: 1466: 1464: 1461: 1457: 1450: 1448: 1446: 1442: 1422: 1411: 1407: 1400: 1397: 1394: 1391: 1388: 1382: 1379: 1376: 1373: 1370: 1360: 1356: 1349: 1346: 1343: 1340: 1337: 1334: 1331: 1325: 1322: 1319: 1316: 1313: 1307: 1296: 1292: 1285: 1282: 1279: 1276: 1273: 1270: 1260: 1256: 1249: 1246: 1243: 1240: 1230: 1229: 1228: 1226: 1222: 1218: 1214: 1213:Avinash Dixit 1210: 1206: 1199: 1197: 1160: 1138: 1134: 1113: 1064: 1005: 1001: 997: 982: 963: 962: 961: 954: 952: 950: 946: 941: 935: 927: 925: 922: 917: 915: 906: 899: 898:Dutch disease 895: 890: 886: 882: 881: 879: 875: 872: 868: 864: 860: 859: 858: 856: 853:rates with a 852: 848: 844: 836: 834: 832: 828: 823: 817: 809: 807: 805: 801: 797: 793: 787: 779: 777: 774: 767: 759: 757: 752: 744: 742: 736: 734: 732: 724: 722: 720: 716: 711: 709: 705: 701: 696: 694: 690: 682: 680: 673: 669: 665: 662: 660: 656: 655: 654: 651: 649: 646:itself, see: 645: 640: 638: 633: 628: 626: 622: 614: 612: 609: 605: 602: 594: 592: 590: 586: 582: 577: 575: 571: 567: 563: 559: 537: 533: 529: 524: 515: 511: 507: 502: 496: 493: 485: 468: 464: 460: 455: 446: 442: 438: 433: 427: 424: 416: 415: 414: 412: 404: 402: 400: 394: 392: 388: 384: 380: 371: 369: 365: 361: 359: 354: 346: 344: 337: 335: 333: 329: 325: 321: 316: 314: 313:macroeconomic 310: 301: 299: 297: 293: 288: 286: 282: 277: 270: 268: 266: 262: 259: 252: 250: 248: 244: 240: 236: 232: 227: 218: 216: 212: 210: 204: 202: 201:profitability 198: 194: 190: 186: 182: 174: 172: 169: 165: 161: 157: 153: 149: 148:Eli Heckscher 145: 141: 137: 132:/hɛkʃrʊˈliːn/ 129: 121: 103: 99: 95: 90: 86: 63: 59: 55: 50: 46: 38:equilibrium ( 37: 32: 19: 2425: 2398: 2377: 2356: 2323: 2319: 2309: 2290: 2283: 2257: 2253: 2218: 2214:Econometrica 2212: 2203: 2185: 2181: 2175: 2157: 2130: 2112:10419/186801 2094: 2090: 2084: 2067: 2063: 2057: 2048: 2044: 2034: 2021:(1): 55–76, 2018: 2014: 2008: 1992: 1988: 1978: 1954: 1950: 1944: 1927: 1923: 1917: 1908: 1899: 1882: 1876: 1870: 1854: 1848: 1842: 1826: 1822: 1818: 1812: 1798: 1789: 1783: 1758: 1750: 1656: 1652: 1638: 1620: 1605: 1601: 1581: 1568: 1560: 1543: 1534: 1525: 1516: 1512: 1503: 1491: 1482: 1478: 1470: 1462: 1458: 1454: 1437: 1225:Paul Krugman 1203: 1153:the country 1027: 958: 937: 918: 913: 910: 870: 866: 842: 840: 819: 789: 769: 754: 740: 728: 712: 697: 686: 677: 652: 641: 631: 629: 618: 610: 606: 598: 588: 584: 578: 573: 569: 565: 564:production, 557: 555: 411:Cobb–Douglas 408: 395: 386: 382: 375: 366: 362: 358:productivity 352: 350: 341: 324:Ronald Jones 317: 305: 289: 278: 274: 264: 263: 258:Bertil Ohlin 256: 246: 239:endogenously 222: 213: 205: 178: 152:Bertil Ohlin 135: 127: 125: 1473:Econometric 921:econometric 884:industries. 855:price index 822:competitive 737:Conclusions 719:Penn effect 715:econometric 621:competition 391:homogeneous 271:2×2×2 model 2436:Categories 2209:Melitz, M. 2051:(1): 19–37 1743:References 1706:Free trade 1647:See also: 700:currencies 644:free trade 625:free trade 302:Extensions 162:theory of 2340:154021080 2276:153816688 2223:CiteSeerX 1621:See also 1451:Criticism 1297:∗ 1261:∗ 998:− 867:worse off 845:concerns 820:Free and 691:, and no 168:resources 136:H–O model 1661:See also 733:exists. 632:relative 235:autarkic 2076:3149288 2001:2951353 1863:1810209 919:Modern 851:nominal 847:nominal 689:tariffs 309:tariffs 193:capital 154:at the 138:) is a 36:Autarky 2386:  2363:  2338:  2298:  2274:  2225:  2164:  2137:  2074:  1999:  1971:117209 1969:  1861:  1823:Kyklos 1771:  1386:  1329:  1126:, and 1028:where 827:rental 806:rate. 804:rental 792:rental 674:market 562:arable 556:where 326:, and 247:within 191:, and 2336:S2CID 2272:S2CID 2072:JSTOR 1997:JSTOR 1967:JSTOR 1859:JSTOR 1546:lathe 1443:with 889:money 668:stock 353:could 197:goods 189:labor 2422:NBER 2384:ISBN 2361:ISBN 2296:ISBN 2162:ISBN 2135:ISBN 1769:ISBN 1492:The 1223:and 1215:and 841:The 831:wage 800:wage 796:wage 185:land 150:and 126:The 2426:can 2328:doi 2262:doi 2258:117 2233:doi 2190:doi 2107:hdl 2099:doi 2023:doi 1959:doi 1932:doi 1887:doi 1831:doi 1765:190 914:and 894:FDI 670:or 639:). 2438:: 2334:, 2322:, 2318:, 2270:, 2256:, 2244:^ 2231:, 2219:71 2217:, 2186:17 2184:, 2148:^ 2121:^ 2105:. 2093:. 2068:97 2066:. 2049:78 2047:, 2043:, 2019:56 2017:, 1993:87 1991:, 1965:, 1955:90 1953:, 1928:29 1926:. 1883:59 1881:. 1855:77 1853:, 1827:21 1825:, 1767:. 1625:. 1618:. 1447:. 1077:, 900:.) 873:). 721:. 650:. 572:, 401:. 334:. 322:, 187:, 134:, 2392:. 2369:. 2330:: 2324:3 2264:: 2235:: 2192:: 2115:. 2109:: 2101:: 2095:3 2078:. 2025:: 1961:: 1938:. 1934:: 1893:. 1889:: 1833:: 1819:N 1806:. 1792:. 1777:. 1423:. 1417:) 1412:W 1408:L 1404:( 1401:r 1398:o 1395:b 1392:a 1389:L 1383:d 1380:l 1377:r 1374:o 1371:W 1366:) 1361:W 1357:K 1353:( 1350:l 1347:a 1344:t 1341:i 1338:p 1335:a 1332:C 1326:d 1323:l 1320:r 1317:o 1314:W 1308:= 1302:) 1293:r 1289:( 1286:l 1283:a 1280:t 1277:n 1274:e 1271:r 1266:) 1257:w 1253:( 1250:e 1247:g 1244:a 1241:w 1182:V 1161:c 1139:C 1135:s 1114:c 1091:C 1087:V 1065:c 1042:C 1038:F 1012:V 1006:C 1002:s 992:C 988:V 983:= 977:C 973:F 589:A 585:F 574:L 570:K 566:F 558:A 538:2 534:/ 530:1 525:L 516:2 512:/ 508:1 503:K 497:= 494:F 469:3 465:/ 461:2 456:L 447:3 443:/ 439:1 434:K 428:= 425:A 387:k 383:k 183:( 130:( 104:B 100:C 96:= 91:A 87:C 64:B 60:A 56:, 51:A 47:A 20:)

Index

Heckscher-Ohlin model

Autarky
Production–possibility frontier
general equilibrium
international trade
Eli Heckscher
Bertil Ohlin
Stockholm School of Economics
David Ricardo's
comparative advantage
resources
factors of production
land
labor
capital
goods
profitability
Labor-intensive
comparative advantage
factor of production
autarkic
endogenously
infrastructure
Bertil Ohlin
developing countries
labor-abundant
comparative advantage
capital-intensive
tariffs

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.