Knowledge

Marginal cost

Source 📝

830:
profit-maximizing quantity and price would not change. This can be illustrated by graphing the short run total cost curve and the short-run variable cost curve. The shapes of the curves are identical. Each curve initially increases at a decreasing rate, reaches an inflection point, then increases at an increasing rate. The only difference between the curves is that the SRVC curve begins from the origin while the SRTC curve originates on the positive part of the vertical axis. The distance of the beginning point of the SRTC above the origin represents the fixed cost – the vertical distance between the curves. This distance remains constant as the quantity produced, Q, increases. MC is the slope of the SRVC curve. A change in fixed cost would be reflected by a change in the vertical distance between the SRTC and SRVC curve. Any such change would have no effect on the shape of the SRVC curve and therefore its slope MC at any point. The changing law of marginal cost is similar to the changing law of average cost. They are both decrease at first with the increase of output, then start to increase after reaching a certain scale. While the output when marginal cost reaches its minimum is smaller than the average total cost and average variable cost. When the average total cost and the average variable cost reach their lowest point, the marginal cost is equal to the average cost.
972:
higher than average cost(n). If the marginal cost is found lying under the average cost curve, it will bend the average cost curve downwards and if the marginal cost is above the average cost curve, it will bend the average cost curve upwards. You can see the table above where before the marginal cost curve and the average cost curve intersect, the average cost curve is downwards sloping, however after the intersection, the average cost curve is sloping upwards. The U-shape graph reflects the law of diminishing returns. A firm can only produce so much but after the production of (n+1)th output reaches a minimum cost, the output produced after will only increase the average total cost (Nwokoye, Ebele & Ilechukwu, Nneamaka, 2018).
800:). Economies of scale are said to exist if an additional unit of output can be produced for less than the average of all previous units – that is, if long-run marginal cost is below long-run average cost, so the latter is falling. Conversely, there may be levels of production where marginal cost is higher than average cost, and the average cost is an increasing function of output. Where there are economies of scale, prices set at marginal cost will fail to cover total costs, thus requiring a subsidy. For this generic case, minimum average cost occurs at the point where average cost and marginal cost are equal (when plotted, the marginal cost curve intersects the average cost curve from below). 981:
black vertical line marked as "profit-maximising quantity" is where the marginal revenue is larger than marginal cost. If a firm sets its production on the left side of the graph and decides to increase the output, the additional revenue per output obtained will exceed the additional cost per output. From the "profit maximizing graph", we could observe that the revenue covers both bar A and B, meanwhile the cost only covers B. Of course A+B earns you a profit but the increase in output to the point of MR=MC yields extra profit that can cover the revenue for the missing A. The firm is recommended to increase output to reach (Theory and Applications of Microeconomics, 2012).
518:. This reduction in productivity is not limited to the additional labor needed to produce the marginal unit – the productivity of every unit of labor is reduced. Thus the cost of producing the marginal unit of output has two components: the cost associated with producing the marginal unit and the increase in average costs for all units produced due to the "damage" to the entire productive process. The first component is the per-unit or average cost. The second component is the small increase in cost due to the law of diminishing marginal returns which increases the costs of all units sold. 964: 812:(the portion of the MC curve below its intersection with the AVC curve is not part of the supply curve because a firm would not operate at a price below the shutdown point). This is not true for firms operating in other market structures. For example, while a monopoly has an MC curve, it does not have a supply curve. In a perfectly competitive market, a supply curve shows the quantity a seller is willing and able to supply at each price – for each price, there is a unique quantity that would be supplied. 302:
unit is high, if the firm operates at too low a level of output, or it may start flat or rise immediately. At some point, the marginal cost rises as increases in the variable inputs such as labor put increasing pressure on the fixed assets such as the size of the building. In the long run, the firm would increase its fixed assets to correspond to the desired output; the short run is defined as the period in which those assets cannot be changed.
989: 290: 311: 1991: 1980: 917: 885: 952: 764:...many more companies state that they have falling, rather than rising, marginal cost curves. While there are reasons to wonder whether respondents interpreted these questions about costs correctly, their answers paint an image of the cost structure of the typical firm that is very different from the one immortalized in textbooks. 346:
Fixed costs represent the costs that do not change as the production quantity changes. Fixed costs are costs incurred by things like rent, building space, machines, etc. Variable costs change as the production quantity changes, and are often associated with labor or materials. The derivative of fixed
301:
On the short run, the firm has some costs that are fixed independently of the quantity of output (e.g. buildings, machinery). Other costs such as labor and materials vary with output, and thus show up in marginal cost. The marginal cost may first decline, as in the diagram, if the additional cost per
984:
On the other hand, the right side of the black line (Marginal revenue = marginal cost), shows that marginal cost is more than marginal revenue. Suppose a firm sets its output on this side, if it reduces the output, the cost will decrease from C and D which exceeds the decrease in revenue which is D.
820:
In perfectly competitive markets, firms decide the quantity to be produced based on marginal costs and sale price. If the sale price is higher than the marginal cost, then they produce the unit and supply it. If the marginal cost is higher than the price, it would not be profitable to produce it. So
46:
of producing additional quantity. In some contexts, it refers to an increment of one unit of output, and in others it refers to the rate of change of total cost as output is increased by an infinitesimal amount. As Figure 1 shows, the marginal cost is measured in dollars per unit, whereas total cost
734:
is the change in quantity of labor that brings about a one-unit change in output. Since the wage rate is assumed constant, marginal cost and marginal product of labor have an inverse relationship—if the marginal product of labor is decreasing (or, increasing), then marginal cost is increasing
432:
For instance, suppose the total cost of making 1 shoe is $ 30 and the total cost of making 2 shoes is $ 40. The marginal cost of producing shoes decreases from $ 30 to $ 10 with the production of the second shoe ($ 40 – $ 30 = $ 10). In another example, when a fixed cost is associated, the marginal
904:
Such externalities are a result of firms externalizing their costs onto a third party in order to reduce their own total cost. As a result of externalizing such costs, we see that members of society who are not included in the firm will be negatively affected by such behavior of the firm. In this
759:
and colleagues conducted a survey of 200 executives of corporations with sales exceeding $ 10 million, in which they were asked, among other questions, about the structure of their marginal cost curves. Strikingly, just 11% of respondents answered that their marginal costs increased as production
513:
Marginal cost is not the cost of producing the "next" or "last" unit. The cost of the last unit is the same as the cost of the first unit and every other unit. In the short run, increasing production requires using more of the variable input — conventionally assumed to be labor. Adding more
980:
The profit maximizing graph on the right side of the page represents optimal production quantity when both marginal cost and the marginal profit line intercepts. The black line represents the intersection where the profits are the greatest (marginal revenue = marginal cost). The left side of the
971:
In this case, when the marginal cost of the (n+1)th unit is less than the average cost(n), the average cost (n+1) will get a smaller value than average cost(n). It goes the opposite way when the marginal cost of (n+1)th is higher than average cost(n). In this case, The average cost(n+1) will be
875:
the environment, and others may bear those costs. A consumer may consume a good which produces benefits for society, such as education; because the individual does not receive all of the benefits, he may consume less than efficiency would suggest. Alternatively, an individual may be a smoker or
321:
is defined as the length of time in which no input is fixed. Everything, including building size and machinery, can be chosen optimally for the quantity of output that is desired. As a result, even if short-run marginal cost rises because of capacity constraints, long-run marginal cost can be
829:
Marginal costs are not affected by the level of fixed cost. Marginal costs can be expressed as ∆C/∆Q. Since fixed costs do not vary with (depend on) changes in quantity, MC is ∆VC/∆Q. Thus if fixed cost were to double, the marginal cost MC would not be affected, and consequently, the
939:
Such production creates a social cost curve that is below the private cost curve. In an equilibrium state, markets creating positive externalities of production will underproduce their good. As a result, the socially optimal production level would be greater than that observed.
297:
Short run marginal cost is the change in total cost when an additional output is produced in the short run and some costs are fixed. On the right side of the page, the short-run marginal cost forms a U-shape, with quantity on the x-axis and cost per unit on the y-axis.
750:
models broadly assume that marginal cost will increase as production increases, several empirical studies conducted throughout the 20th century have concluded that the marginal cost is either constant or falling for the vast majority of firms. Most recently, former
892:
Much of the time, private and social costs do not diverge from one another, but at times social costs may be either greater or less than private costs. When the marginal social cost of production is greater than that of the private cost function, there is a
62:
of the factory building that do not change with output. The marginal cost can be either short-run or long-run marginal cost, depending on what costs vary with output, since in the long run even building size is chosen to fit the desired output.
326:
if technological or management productivity changes with the quantity. Or, there may be both, as in the diagram at the right, in which the marginal cost first falls (increasing returns to scale) and then rises (decreasing returns to scale).
959:
Say the starting point of level of output produced is n. Marginal cost is the change of the total cost from an additional output . Therefore, (refer to "Average cost" labelled picture on the right side of the screen.
688: 521:
Marginal costs can also be expressed as the cost per unit of labor divided by the marginal product of labor. Denoting variable cost as VC, the constant wage rate as w, and labor usage as L, we have
429:, marginal cost equals the change in total (or variable) cost that comes with each additional unit produced. Since fixed cost does not change in the short run, it has no effect on marginal cost. 908:
In an equilibrium state, markets creating negative externalities of production will overproduce that good. As a result, the socially optimal production level would be lower than that observed.
571: 420: 256: 796:
apply to the long run, a span of time in which all inputs can be varied by the firm so that there are no fixed inputs or fixed costs. Production may be subject to economies of scale (or
732: 201: 54:
At each level of production and time period being considered, marginal cost includes all costs that vary with the level of production, whereas costs that do not vary with production are
932:
is a textbook example of production that creates positive externalities. An example of such a public good, which creates a divergence in social and private costs, is the production of
864:, of both production and consumption. Examples include a social cost from air pollution affecting third parties and a social benefit from flu shots protecting others from infection. 612: 985:
Therefore, decreasing output until the point of (marginal revenue=marginal cost) will lead to an increase in profit (Theory and Applications of Microeconomics, 2012).
279: 852:
costs. The marginal private cost shows the cost borne by the firm in question. It is the marginal private cost that is used by business decision makers in their
114: 134: 87: 860:
any other cost (or offsetting benefit) to parties having no direct association with purchase or sale of the product. It incorporates all negative and positive
58:. For example, the marginal cost of producing an automobile will include the costs of labor and parts needed for the additional automobile but not the 1861: 1360: 948:
The marginal cost intersects with the average total cost and the average variable cost at their lowest point. Take the graph as a representation.
1161: 808:
The portion of the marginal cost curve above its intersection with the average variable cost curve is the supply curve for a firm operating in a
47:
is in dollars, and the marginal cost is the slope of the total cost, the rate at which it increases with output. Marginal cost is different from
1204: 876:
alcoholic and impose costs on others. In these cases, production or consumption of the good in question may differ from the optimum level.
936:. It is often seen that education is a positive for any whole society, as well as a positive for those directly involved in the market. 620: 760:
increased, while 48% answered that they were constant, and 41% answered that they were decreasing. Summing up the results, they wrote:
905:
case, an increased cost of production in society creates a social cost curve that depicts a greater cost than the private cost curve.
1237: 1098: 1078: 1123: 1552: 1353: 1846: 1798: 1486: 1023: 527: 365: 212: 1320: 2020: 1508: 1496: 1491: 1481: 1451: 963: 700: 339:
are expressed as follows, where Q represents the production quantity, VC represents variable costs, FC represents
1926: 1402: 1048: 856:
behavior. Marginal social cost is similar to private cost in that it includes the cost of private enterprise but
694: 142: 1592: 1461: 1162:
http://ocw.mit.edu/courses/economics/14-01-principles-of-microeconomics-fall-2007/lecture-notes/14_01_lec13.pdf
778: 1151:
Silberberg & Suen, The Structure of Economics, A Mathematical Analysis 3rd ed. (McGraw-Hill 2001) at 181.
1994: 1891: 1886: 1836: 1709: 1587: 1346: 929: 90: 577: 1911: 1871: 1866: 1648: 1619: 1476: 1398: 1028: 747: 318: 1856: 1841: 1557: 1266:"Piana V. (2011), Refusal to sell – a key concept in Economics and Management, Economics Web Institute." 868: 797: 693:
Here MPL is the ratio of increase in the quantity produced per unit increase in labour: i.e. ΔQ/ΔL, the
1173:
Chia-Hui Chen, course materials for 14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007. MIT OpenCourseWare (
924:
When the marginal social cost of production is less than that of the private cost function, there is a
901:
or other environmental waste are textbook examples of production that creates negative externalities.
1906: 1826: 1758: 1673: 1567: 1503: 1043: 925: 894: 785:
theories of the firm, which generally assume that marginal cost is constant as production increases.
1281: 1921: 1748: 1597: 1540: 1383: 1008: 853: 809: 782: 515: 1265: 1831: 1777: 1704: 1614: 1572: 1562: 1530: 1525: 1471: 1466: 793: 352: 1090: 1964: 1952: 1931: 1901: 1763: 1687: 1643: 1233: 1200: 1119: 1094: 1038: 264: 1916: 1896: 1803: 1753: 1724: 1582: 1547: 1444: 1422: 1082: 1053: 1033: 347:
cost is zero, and this term drops out of the marginal cost equation: that is, marginal cost
323: 844:
Of great importance in the theory of marginal cost is the distinction between the marginal
206:
If the cost function is not differentiable, the marginal cost can be expressed as follows:
1984: 1456: 1393: 752: 988: 867:
Externalities are costs (or benefits) that are not borne by the parties to the economic
289: 96: 2015: 1959: 1699: 1658: 1577: 1369: 821:
the production will be carried out until the marginal cost is equal to the sale price.
310: 119: 72: 2009: 1881: 1781: 1772: 1743: 1729: 1719: 1663: 1427: 1407: 1302: 1083: 861: 1252:
Vickrey W. (2008) "Marginal and Average Cost Pricing". In: Palgrave Macmillan (eds)
514:
labor to a fixed capital stock reduces the marginal product of labor because of the
1851: 1683: 1678: 1412: 1286: 1223: 1003: 756: 48: 1227: 1194: 116:
is the first derivative of the cost function with respect to the output quantity
1876: 1788: 1668: 1520: 1434: 1190: 839: 17: 1636: 1388: 1058: 1018: 340: 336: 67: 59: 55: 39: 1947: 1714: 1631: 1626: 1439: 933: 898: 872: 31: 1979: 1739: 1734: 1609: 426: 916: 884: 1793: 1692: 1604: 951: 1138:
The classic reference is Jakob Viner, "Cost Curves and Supply Curve",
1768: 1229:
Asking About Prices: A New Approach to Understanding Price Stickiness
770:
Asking About Prices: A New Approach to Understanding Price Stickiness
51:, which is the total cost divided by the number of units produced. 27:
Cost added by producing one additional unit of a product or service
1653: 1535: 1515: 987: 962: 950: 915: 883: 683:{\displaystyle MC={\frac {w\Delta L}{\Delta Q}}={\frac {w}{MPL}}.} 309: 288: 1338: 355:(ATC), which is the total cost (including fixed costs, denoted C 1810: 1226:; Canetti, Elie R. D.; Lebow, David E.; Rudd, Jeremy B. (1998). 1013: 781:
have pointed to these results as evidence in favor of their own
43: 1342: 1321:"Theory and Applications of Microeconomics - Table of Contents" 1199:. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc. p. 151. 42:
that arises when the quantity produced is increased, i.e. the
1301:
Nwokoye, Ebele Stella; Ilechukwu, Nneamaka (2018-08-06).
1177:), Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Downloaded on . 1089:. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall. p.  955:
Relationship between marginal cost and average total cost
944:
Relationship between marginal cost and average total cost
433:
cost can be calculated as presented in the table below.
335:
In the simplest case, the total cost function and its
1174: 703: 623: 580: 530: 368: 267: 215: 145: 122: 99: 75: 322:
constant. Or, there may be increasing or decreasing
1940: 1819: 1376: 897:of production. Productive processes that result in 735:(decreasing), and AVC = VC/Q=wL/Q = w/(Q/L) = w/AP 726: 682: 606: 565: 414: 273: 250: 195: 128: 108: 81: 1218: 1216: 566:{\displaystyle MC={\frac {\Delta VC}{\Delta Q}}} 415:{\displaystyle ATC={\frac {C_{0}+\Delta C}{Q}}.} 251:{\displaystyle MC={\frac {\Delta C}{\Delta Q}},} 762: 331:Cost functions and relationship to average cost 1354: 8: 727:{\displaystyle {\frac {\Delta L}{\Delta Q}}} 359:) divided by the number of units produced: 281:denotes an incremental change of one unit. 196:{\displaystyle MC(Q)={\frac {\ dC}{\ dQ}}.} 1361: 1347: 1339: 1196:Post-Keynesian Economics: New Foundations 704: 702: 659: 633: 622: 593: 579: 540: 529: 388: 381: 367: 266: 225: 214: 164: 144: 121: 98: 74: 1282:"Marginal Cost Of Production Definition" 1254:The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 1185: 1183: 435: 1070: 816:Decisions taken based on marginal costs 351:fixed costs. This can be compared with 1232:. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. 1114:Simon, Carl; Blume, Lawrence (1994). 607:{\displaystyle \Delta VC={w\Delta L}} 7: 920:Positive Externalities of Production 912:Positive externalities of production 888:Negative Externalities of Production 880:Negative externalities of production 834:Private versus social marginal cost 1917:Microfoundations of macroeconomics 804:Perfectly competitive supply curve 715: 707: 697:. The last equality holds because 647: 639: 597: 581: 554: 543: 397: 268: 236: 228: 25: 425:For discrete calculation without 1990: 1989: 1978: 1140:Zeitschrift fur Nationalokonomie 1085:Economics: Principles in Action 871:. A producer may, for example, 742:Empirical data on marginal cost 343:and TC represents total costs. 1303:"CHAPTER FIVE THEORY OF COSTS" 1118:. W. W. Norton & Company. 1081:; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). 158: 152: 1: 1256:. Palgrave Macmillan, London 928:of production. Production of 810:perfectly competitive market 516:diminishing marginal returns 1862:Civil engineering economics 1847:Statistical decision theory 1487:Income elasticity of demand 1024:Cost-Volume-Profit Analysis 825:Relationship to fixed costs 2037: 1497:Price elasticity of supply 1492:Price elasticity of demand 1482:Cross elasticity of demand 1116:Mathematics for Economists 837: 1973: 1049:Marginal product of labor 779:Post-Keynesian economists 695:marginal product of labor 1553:Income–consumption curve 1280:Bio, Full (2021-05-19). 1887:Industrial organization 992:Profit Maximizing Graph 293:Short Run Marginal Cost 285:Short run marginal cost 274:{\displaystyle \Delta } 1029:Cost-sharing mechanism 993: 968: 956: 921: 889: 775: 728: 684: 608: 567: 437:Marginal Cost Example 416: 315: 314:Long Run Marginal Cost 306:Long run marginal cost 294: 275: 252: 197: 130: 110: 83: 1857:Engineering economics 1452:Cost–benefit analysis 991: 966: 954: 919: 887: 798:diseconomies of scale 729: 685: 609: 568: 417: 313: 292: 276: 253: 198: 131: 111: 84: 38:is the change in the 1674:Price discrimination 1568:Intertemporal choice 1044:Marginal factor cost 926:positive externality 895:negative externality 701: 621: 578: 528: 366: 265: 213: 143: 120: 97: 93:, the marginal cost 73: 1985:Business portal 1922:Operations research 1749:Substitution effect 1009:Break even analysis 976:Profit maximization 854:profit maximization 438: 1563:Indifference curve 1531:Goods and services 1472:Economies of scope 1467:Economies of scale 1175:http://ocw.mit.edu 1142:, 3:23-46 (1932). 1079:O'Sullivan, Arthur 994: 969: 957: 922: 890: 794:Economies of scale 789:Economies of scale 724: 680: 604: 563: 436: 412: 353:average total cost 349:does not depend on 316: 295: 271: 248: 193: 126: 109:{\displaystyle MC} 106: 89:is continuous and 79: 2021:Marginal concepts 2003: 2002: 1965:Political economy 1764:Supply and demand 1644:Pareto efficiency 1325:2012 Book Archive 1206:978-1-84720-483-7 1039:Marginal concepts 722: 675: 654: 561: 511: 510: 407: 243: 188: 180: 169: 129:{\displaystyle Q} 82:{\displaystyle C} 16:(Redirected from 2028: 1993: 1992: 1983: 1982: 1725:Returns to scale 1583:Market structure 1363: 1356: 1349: 1340: 1335: 1333: 1332: 1316: 1314: 1313: 1297: 1295: 1294: 1268: 1263: 1257: 1250: 1244: 1243: 1224:Blinder, Alan S. 1220: 1211: 1210: 1187: 1178: 1171: 1165: 1158: 1152: 1149: 1143: 1136: 1130: 1129: 1111: 1105: 1104: 1088: 1075: 1054:Marginal revenue 1034:Economic surplus 773: 733: 731: 730: 725: 723: 721: 713: 705: 689: 687: 686: 681: 676: 674: 660: 655: 653: 645: 634: 613: 611: 610: 605: 603: 572: 570: 569: 564: 562: 560: 552: 541: 439: 421: 419: 418: 413: 408: 403: 393: 392: 382: 324:returns to scale 280: 278: 277: 272: 257: 255: 254: 249: 244: 242: 234: 226: 202: 200: 199: 194: 189: 187: 178: 176: 167: 165: 135: 133: 132: 127: 115: 113: 112: 107: 88: 86: 85: 80: 21: 18:Incremental cost 2036: 2035: 2031: 2030: 2029: 2027: 2026: 2025: 2006: 2005: 2004: 1999: 1977: 1969: 1936: 1815: 1457:Deadweight loss 1394:Consumer choice 1372: 1367: 1330: 1328: 1319: 1311: 1309: 1300: 1292: 1290: 1279: 1276: 1271: 1264: 1260: 1251: 1247: 1240: 1222: 1221: 1214: 1207: 1189: 1188: 1181: 1172: 1168: 1159: 1155: 1150: 1146: 1137: 1133: 1126: 1113: 1112: 1108: 1101: 1077: 1076: 1072: 1068: 1063: 999: 978: 946: 914: 882: 842: 836: 827: 818: 806: 791: 774: 768: 753:Federal Reserve 744: 738: 714: 706: 699: 698: 664: 646: 635: 619: 618: 576: 575: 553: 542: 526: 525: 459:10 (Fixed Cost) 384: 383: 364: 363: 358: 333: 308: 287: 263: 262: 235: 227: 211: 210: 177: 166: 141: 140: 118: 117: 95: 94: 71: 70: 28: 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 2034: 2032: 2024: 2023: 2018: 2008: 2007: 2001: 2000: 1998: 1997: 1987: 1974: 1971: 1970: 1968: 1967: 1962: 1960:Macroeconomics 1957: 1956: 1955: 1944: 1942: 1938: 1937: 1935: 1934: 1929: 1924: 1919: 1914: 1909: 1904: 1899: 1894: 1889: 1884: 1879: 1874: 1869: 1864: 1859: 1854: 1849: 1844: 1839: 1834: 1829: 1823: 1821: 1817: 1816: 1814: 1813: 1808: 1807: 1806: 1801: 1791: 1786: 1785: 1784: 1775: 1761: 1756: 1751: 1746: 1737: 1732: 1727: 1722: 1717: 1712: 1707: 1702: 1697: 1696: 1695: 1690: 1681: 1676: 1671: 1666: 1661: 1659:Price controls 1651: 1646: 1641: 1640: 1639: 1634: 1629: 1624: 1623: 1622: 1617: 1607: 1602: 1601: 1600: 1595: 1580: 1578:Market failure 1575: 1570: 1565: 1560: 1555: 1550: 1545: 1544: 1543: 1538: 1528: 1523: 1518: 1513: 1512: 1511: 1501: 1500: 1499: 1494: 1489: 1484: 1474: 1469: 1464: 1459: 1454: 1449: 1448: 1447: 1442: 1437: 1432: 1431: 1430: 1420: 1415: 1405: 1396: 1391: 1386: 1380: 1378: 1374: 1373: 1370:Microeconomics 1368: 1366: 1365: 1358: 1351: 1343: 1337: 1336: 1317: 1298: 1275: 1274:External links 1272: 1270: 1269: 1258: 1245: 1238: 1212: 1205: 1179: 1166: 1153: 1144: 1131: 1124: 1106: 1099: 1069: 1067: 1064: 1062: 1061: 1056: 1051: 1046: 1041: 1036: 1031: 1026: 1021: 1016: 1011: 1006: 1000: 998: 995: 977: 974: 945: 942: 913: 910: 881: 878: 838:Main article: 835: 832: 826: 823: 817: 814: 805: 802: 790: 787: 766: 743: 740: 736: 720: 717: 712: 709: 691: 690: 679: 673: 670: 667: 663: 658: 652: 649: 644: 641: 638: 632: 629: 626: 615: 614: 602: 599: 596: 592: 589: 586: 583: 573: 559: 556: 551: 548: 545: 539: 536: 533: 509: 508: 505: 502: 499: 495: 494: 491: 488: 485: 481: 480: 477: 474: 471: 467: 466: 463: 460: 457: 453: 452: 451:Marginal Cost 449: 446: 443: 442:Output (units) 423: 422: 411: 406: 402: 399: 396: 391: 387: 380: 377: 374: 371: 356: 332: 329: 307: 304: 286: 283: 270: 259: 258: 247: 241: 238: 233: 230: 224: 221: 218: 204: 203: 192: 186: 183: 175: 172: 163: 160: 157: 154: 151: 148: 125: 105: 102: 91:differentiable 78: 26: 24: 14: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 2033: 2022: 2019: 2017: 2014: 2013: 2011: 1996: 1988: 1986: 1981: 1976: 1975: 1972: 1966: 1963: 1961: 1958: 1954: 1951: 1950: 1949: 1946: 1945: 1943: 1939: 1933: 1930: 1928: 1925: 1923: 1920: 1918: 1915: 1913: 1910: 1908: 1905: 1903: 1900: 1898: 1895: 1893: 1892:Institutional 1890: 1888: 1885: 1883: 1880: 1878: 1875: 1873: 1870: 1868: 1865: 1863: 1860: 1858: 1855: 1853: 1850: 1848: 1845: 1843: 1840: 1838: 1837:Computational 1835: 1833: 1830: 1828: 1825: 1824: 1822: 1818: 1812: 1809: 1805: 1802: 1800: 1797: 1796: 1795: 1792: 1790: 1787: 1783: 1782:Law of supply 1779: 1776: 1774: 1773:Law of demand 1770: 1767: 1766: 1765: 1762: 1760: 1759:Social choice 1757: 1755: 1752: 1750: 1747: 1745: 1744:Excess supply 1741: 1738: 1736: 1733: 1731: 1730:Risk aversion 1728: 1726: 1723: 1721: 1718: 1716: 1713: 1711: 1708: 1706: 1703: 1701: 1698: 1694: 1691: 1689: 1685: 1682: 1680: 1677: 1675: 1672: 1670: 1667: 1665: 1664:Price ceiling 1662: 1660: 1657: 1656: 1655: 1652: 1650: 1647: 1645: 1642: 1638: 1635: 1633: 1630: 1628: 1625: 1621: 1620:Complementary 1618: 1616: 1613: 1612: 1611: 1608: 1606: 1603: 1599: 1596: 1594: 1591: 1590: 1589: 1586: 1585: 1584: 1581: 1579: 1576: 1574: 1571: 1569: 1566: 1564: 1561: 1559: 1556: 1554: 1551: 1549: 1546: 1542: 1539: 1537: 1534: 1533: 1532: 1529: 1527: 1524: 1522: 1519: 1517: 1514: 1510: 1507: 1506: 1505: 1502: 1498: 1495: 1493: 1490: 1488: 1485: 1483: 1480: 1479: 1478: 1475: 1473: 1470: 1468: 1465: 1463: 1460: 1458: 1455: 1453: 1450: 1446: 1443: 1441: 1438: 1436: 1433: 1429: 1426: 1425: 1424: 1421: 1419: 1416: 1414: 1411: 1410: 1409: 1406: 1404: 1403:non-convexity 1400: 1397: 1395: 1392: 1390: 1387: 1385: 1382: 1381: 1379: 1375: 1371: 1364: 1359: 1357: 1352: 1350: 1345: 1344: 1341: 1326: 1322: 1318: 1308: 1304: 1299: 1289: 1288: 1283: 1278: 1277: 1273: 1267: 1262: 1259: 1255: 1249: 1246: 1241: 1239:0-87154-121-1 1235: 1231: 1230: 1225: 1219: 1217: 1213: 1208: 1202: 1198: 1197: 1192: 1186: 1184: 1180: 1176: 1170: 1167: 1163: 1157: 1154: 1148: 1145: 1141: 1135: 1132: 1127: 1121: 1117: 1110: 1107: 1102: 1100:0-13-063085-3 1096: 1092: 1087: 1086: 1080: 1074: 1071: 1065: 1060: 1057: 1055: 1052: 1050: 1047: 1045: 1042: 1040: 1037: 1035: 1032: 1030: 1027: 1025: 1022: 1020: 1017: 1015: 1012: 1010: 1007: 1005: 1002: 1001: 996: 990: 986: 982: 975: 973: 965: 961: 953: 949: 943: 941: 937: 935: 931: 927: 918: 911: 909: 906: 902: 900: 896: 886: 879: 877: 874: 870: 865: 863: 862:externalities 859: 855: 851: 847: 841: 833: 831: 824: 822: 815: 813: 811: 803: 801: 799: 795: 788: 786: 784: 780: 771: 765: 761: 758: 754: 749: 741: 739: 718: 710: 696: 677: 671: 668: 665: 661: 656: 650: 642: 636: 630: 627: 624: 617: 616: 600: 594: 590: 587: 584: 574: 557: 549: 546: 537: 534: 531: 524: 523: 522: 519: 517: 506: 503: 500: 497: 496: 492: 489: 486: 483: 482: 478: 475: 472: 469: 468: 464: 461: 458: 455: 454: 450: 447: 444: 441: 440: 434: 430: 428: 409: 404: 400: 394: 389: 385: 378: 375: 372: 369: 362: 361: 360: 354: 350: 344: 342: 338: 330: 328: 325: 320: 312: 305: 303: 299: 291: 284: 282: 245: 239: 231: 222: 219: 216: 209: 208: 207: 190: 184: 181: 173: 170: 161: 155: 149: 146: 139: 138: 137: 123: 103: 100: 92: 76: 69: 68:cost function 64: 61: 57: 52: 50: 45: 41: 37: 36:marginal cost 33: 19: 1927:Optimization 1912:Mathematical 1872:Experimental 1867:Evolutionary 1852:Econometrics 1710:Public goods 1684:Price system 1679:Price signal 1593:Monopolistic 1462:Distribution 1417: 1377:Major topics 1329:. Retrieved 1327:. 2012-12-29 1324: 1310:. Retrieved 1307:ResearchGate 1306: 1291:. Retrieved 1287:Investopedia 1285: 1261: 1253: 1248: 1228: 1195: 1191:Lavoie, Marc 1169: 1156: 1147: 1139: 1134: 1115: 1109: 1084: 1073: 1004:Average cost 983: 979: 970: 967:Average cost 958: 947: 938: 930:public goods 923: 907: 903: 891: 866: 857: 849: 845: 843: 828: 819: 807: 792: 776: 769: 763: 757:Alan Blinder 748:neoclassical 745: 692: 520: 512: 448:Average Cost 431: 424: 348: 345: 334: 319:The long run 317: 300: 296: 260: 205: 65: 53: 49:average cost 35: 29: 1877:Game theory 1842:Development 1789:Uncertainty 1669:Price floor 1649:Preferences 1588:Competition 1558:Information 1521:Externality 1504:Equilibrium 1445:Transaction 1423:Opportunity 1384:Aggregation 1059:Merit goods 869:transaction 840:Social cost 755:Vice-Chair 341:fixed costs 2010:Categories 1907:Managerial 1827:Behavioral 1700:Production 1637:Oligopsony 1477:Elasticity 1389:Budget set 1331:2021-05-28 1312:2021-05-28 1293:2021-05-28 1125:0393957330 1066:References 1019:Cost curve 445:Total Cost 337:derivative 60:fixed cost 40:total cost 1948:Economics 1820:Subfields 1715:Rationing 1632:Oligopoly 1627:Monopsony 1615:Bilateral 1548:Household 1399:Convexity 934:education 899:pollution 783:heterodox 716:Δ 708:Δ 648:Δ 640:Δ 598:Δ 582:Δ 555:Δ 544:Δ 398:Δ 269:Δ 237:Δ 229:Δ 32:economics 1995:Category 1941:See also 1832:Business 1804:Marginal 1799:Expected 1740:Shortage 1735:Scarcity 1610:Monopoly 1516:Exchange 1428:Implicit 1418:Marginal 1193:(2014). 997:See also 772:, p. 105 767:—  427:calculus 1953:Applied 1932:Welfare 1794:Utility 1754:Surplus 1693:Pricing 1605:Duopoly 1598:Perfect 1541:Service 1509:General 1413:Average 873:pollute 846:private 66:If the 34:, the 1778:Supply 1769:Demand 1705:Profit 1573:Market 1435:Social 1236:  1203:  1122:  1097:  850:social 746:While 261:where 179:  168:  2016:Costs 1897:Labor 1882:Green 1654:Price 1536:Goods 1526:Firms 777:Many 56:fixed 1811:Wage 1720:Rent 1688:Free 1440:Sunk 1408:Cost 1401:and 1234:ISBN 1201:ISBN 1160:See 1120:ISBN 1095:ISBN 1014:Cost 858:also 848:and 44:cost 1902:Law 1091:111 493:10 479:20 30:In 2012:: 1323:. 1305:. 1284:. 1215:^ 1182:^ 1093:. 507:8 504:16 501:48 490:20 487:40 476:30 473:30 465:- 136:: 1780:/ 1771:/ 1742:/ 1686:/ 1362:e 1355:t 1348:v 1334:. 1315:. 1296:. 1242:. 1209:. 1164:. 1128:. 1103:. 737:L 719:Q 711:L 678:. 672:L 669:P 666:M 662:w 657:= 651:Q 643:L 637:w 631:= 628:C 625:M 601:L 595:w 591:= 588:C 585:V 558:Q 550:C 547:V 538:= 535:C 532:M 498:3 484:2 470:1 462:∞ 456:0 410:. 405:Q 401:C 395:+ 390:0 386:C 379:= 376:C 373:T 370:A 357:0 246:, 240:Q 232:C 223:= 220:C 217:M 191:. 185:Q 182:d 174:C 171:d 162:= 159:) 156:Q 153:( 150:C 147:M 124:Q 104:C 101:M 77:C 20:)

Index

Incremental cost
economics
total cost
cost
average cost
fixed
fixed cost
cost function
differentiable


The long run
returns to scale
derivative
fixed costs
average total cost
calculus
diminishing marginal returns
marginal product of labor
neoclassical
Federal Reserve
Alan Blinder
Post-Keynesian economists
heterodox
Economies of scale
diseconomies of scale
perfectly competitive market
Social cost
profit maximization
externalities

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.