Knowledge (XXG)

Rice broker

Source 📝

300:
The shogunate tried to repair and regulate the economy, in particular the monetary supply and monetary value of rice, but to no avail. Seemingly, if anyone understood the economic developments incurred by the rice-brokers, it was the rice-brokers alone. Since the samurai's income was in fixed amounts of rice, not monetary value, the debasement of the value of rice affected their wealth drastically, and the inflation created by governmental attempts to control the supply of metal coinage had similar effects. In all of this turmoil, the rice-brokers were nearly the only ones to profit.
165:
powerfully but indirectly, prices across the country. This effect was enhanced by the tight monopolistic control of the merchants of this central market over the rice trade across the entire city; nowhere else was wholesale trade in rice permitted. As the business grew, the rice dealers developed among their membership transporters and guards who tightly controlled the flow of rice into the city. These jobs would become more specialized and organized as the 15th century went on, developing into distinctly separate branches of the guild.
31: 43: 256:
serving as reserve backing. This, however, quickly led to the problem of samurai living beyond their means, spending more in order to maintain the kind of lifestyle expected of their status than they could hope to repay. The rice brokers, more often than not, found it easiest to simply allow samurai and
299:
became less and less able to pay back the loans, and an incredible volume of debts were simply rolled over or ignored. The money supply the banks had created also grew out of control, becoming an essential aspect of the nation’s economy, causing serious economic consequences whenever it was altered.
303:
At the beginning of the 19th century, in response to growing inflation, and to the power of the rice brokers, and the merchant class in general, the shogunate once again imposed a series of heavy regulations and restrictions. Easily one of the most damaging was a proscription against receiving loan
164:
Rice dealers in Kyoto gained business very quickly, and became increasingly organized over the course of the 14th century; by 1400, the need for a central rice market was felt. Established sometime around that year, the Kyoto central rice market set rice prices by an auctioning system, determining,
279:
ideals and seeking reform. Thus, the shogunate stepped in, and sought to control the country's economic development, and the growing wealth and power of the merchant class, by organizing and regulating a series of guilds, and by passing strict sumptuary laws forbidding merchants from behaving like
181:
Cattle brokers, and merchants of marine products such as salt and fish saw significant growth and development in this period as well. Kyoto also saw the continuing emergence and development of a monetary economy. Rice would not be fully replaced by coin, however, until the late Edo or early Meiji
168:
An incident in 1431 illustrates the power of the Kyoto rice merchants; they conspired to cut down on the supply of rice to the market, in order to drive prices up. Ordered by the Imperial Court to resume selling rice at a fair rate, they did so for one day and then stopped selling rice altogether.
205:
could be transported easily in a cart, most crops were harvested in such volume that a caravan of packhorses or carts across the rough and dangerous roads, transported by the individual farmers, simply could not work out. Thus, a number of towns served as waystations where merchants would act as
247:
s rice and issued paper bills, representations of value, in exchange. This was probably the first paper money in Japan, but the concept was picked up quickly, and the credit of the brokers was good enough to warrant the kind of trust that such a system relies upon. Many merchants throughout the
255:
and samurai, who promised to pay it back with the tax revenue of future seasons. For a time, this worked quite well for both samurai and brokers, whose system developed into something much more akin to a modern bank; transactions began to be done entirely in paper, with the rice only nominally
144:
As urbanization and other economic shifts became significantly widespread and powerful in the 14th century, the growth of towns created a growth in demand for the transport of produce, particularly rice, into the towns, from increasingly larger and further rural areas. As a result, a system of
189:, however, in 1467, brought these developments, and the merchants behind them to an abrupt halt. The various shops and warehouses that made up the central rice market were quickly sold for very low prices, and the city saw terrible violence and destruction in the ensuing years. 173:
was sent to arrest and punish the ringleaders, little was done, as the Deputy-Governor was party to the conspiracy. The merchants continued to abuse their power, encouraged by the ease of doing so and the rampant corruption which spread as high up as the wife of Shƍgun
226:
of rice, an amount equal to the amount of rice a man eats in a year. Though there was a unified national system of coinage, every feudal domain was free to mint its own coinage as well. Thus, paying for hotels, inns, and food were complicated and difficult affairs for
206:
middlemen, storing farmers’ goods and transporting them to major trade centers such as Osaka, for a price. However, increasing supply and demand towards the end of the 17th century necessitated a better method of transporting goods in large amounts. Merchants in
210:, Osaka, and a number of other ports addressed this problem, testing the use of large ships to transport goods along the coasts. By the end of the 17th century, Osaka was home to at least 24 freight shippers to Edo, and a complex system of 85:
several hundred years earlier; the early rice brokers of Kyoto, however, operated somewhat differently, and were ultimately not nearly as powerful or economically influential as the later Osaka system would be.
291:
Over the course of the 17th and 18th centuries, these Osaka-based institutions grew more solidly into what can legitimately be called banks, focusing their efforts largely on loans to the
275:
were so indebted to the brokers that they could never hope to be able to pay them back; this was a huge problem for the brokers. A new shƍgun came to power at this time, motivated by
201:
system. A major obstacle to the development of a modern capitalistic system in Japan at this time was the problem of transportation. While some commodities, such as woven silk and
240:
Thus, a system of rice warehouses arose, evolving naturally out of the rice storehouses which formed a part of this trade network. Centered in Osaka, the rice brokers bought the
284:
was born, incorporating and organizing the rice brokers in the north of Osaka. The system became formally backed by the shogunate, who acted through the Rice Exchange to affect
251:
Soon afterwards, these rice brokers took the next natural, logical, step towards becoming true financial institutions. They began to loan the paper money to
248:
country were willing to exchange the paper bills for metal coins or bars, recognizing that the Osaka brokers would take back the bills, as payment for rice.
185:
The economy of Kyoto, at least in the eyes (and coffers) of the merchants, flourished in the first two-thirds of the 15th century. The outbreak of the
308:. By the 1860s, which saw the end of the Tokugawa shogunate, the Osaka rice brokers had also disappeared, replaced by other merchant institutions. 271:
This inflated economy came crashing down at the end of Genroku, in the first decade of the 18th century. By this point, many samurai and
128:
Rice brokers also managed, to a great extent, the transportation of rice around the country, organizing the income and wealth of many
424: 214:, both in Osaka proper and in the surrounding area, dealing in cotton, sugar, paper, and the produce of particular regions. 268:
and samurai spent beyond their means, and merchants, who on the whole enjoyed immense profits, spent frivolously as well.
197:
By 1700 or so, Osaka had become the mercantile center of Japan. Osaka merchants had organized themselves into a national
260:
to postpone repayment of the loans, or to default on them entirely. The last decade or so of the 17th century, the
419: 366: 281: 149:
emerged. This process was much the same as the one which would catapult Japan into the modern era in the
113:
s rice in exchange for a fee, trading it for either coin or a form of receipt; essentially a precursor to
161:, which would become the commercial center of a nationwide trade system three hundred years later. 175: 125:
grew poorer and began taking out more loans, increasing the social position of the rice brokers.
280:
higher-class citizens (i.e. samurai, nobles). Sanctioned and encouraged by the shogunate, the
74: 285: 30: 233: 198: 170: 413: 264:
period, is today widely considered to have been the peak of Edo period extravagance;
78: 276: 207: 42: 402: 211: 186: 295:. However, as the peace and stability caused the feudal system to break down, 150: 70: 349: 340:
tax payments to the shogunate. The rice brokers, like other elements of the
103: 17: 394: 90: 121:, and would become quite wealthy and powerful. As the Edo period wore on, 367:
https://web.archive.org/web/20061130143059/http://www.ac.wwu.edu/~kaplan/
114: 352:
pleasure district, and other aspects of the urban culture of the time.
325: 261: 51: 35: 345: 99: 333: 158: 154: 146: 82: 62: 47: 41: 34:
Nihonbashi bridge in Edo, Rice brokers." 36 Views of Mount Fuji "
29: 222: 202: 118: 95: 66: 94:(feudal lords) received most of their income in the form of 344:(townspeople) society in Edo, were frequent patrons of the 231:
traveling to or from Edo as mandated by the shogunate's
363:
The Cultures of East Asia: Political-Material Aspects
320:(æœ­ć·ź, "note/bill exchange"), and were located in the 153:, but on a smaller scale, more localized around the 376:. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. 117:. Many if not all of these rice brokers also made 336:and as middlemen organizing the logistics of 46:Rice polishing by water mill in early modern 8: 324:(è””ć‰, "before the storehouses") section of 61:, which rose to power and significance in 102:in Osaka and Edo thus began to organize 220:income at this time was in the form of 157:area, and centered at Kyoto instead of 145:material transport and warehousing in 27:Forerunners to bankers in feudal Japan 7: 316:The rice brokers in Edo were called 383:. 1963: Stanford University Press. 132:and paying taxes on behalf of the 81:. The concept originally arose in 77:, were the forerunners to Japan's 25: 237:(alternate attendance) system. 169:When the Deputy-Governor of the 328:. A very profitable business, 1: 381:A History of Japan: 1615–1867 374:A History of Japan: 1334–1615 365:. Chap. 16. 09 Nov 2006. < 50:. " 36 Views of Mount Fuji " 441: 136:out of their storehouses. 106:where they would store a 406:– another style of guild 425:Economy of feudal Japan 379:Sansom, George Bailey. 372:Sansom, George (1961). 55: 39: 45: 33: 282:Dƍjima Rice Exchange 176:Ashikaga Yoshimasa 56: 40: 398:– a type of guild 16:(Redirected from 432: 420:Banking in Japan 246: 112: 75:Japanese history 21: 440: 439: 435: 434: 433: 431: 430: 429: 410: 409: 390: 361:Kaplan, Edward 358: 314: 286:monetary policy 244: 195: 142: 110: 73:(1603-1867) of 28: 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 438: 436: 428: 427: 422: 412: 411: 408: 407: 399: 389: 386: 385: 384: 377: 370: 357: 354: 332:acted both as 313: 310: 304:payments from 194: 191: 171:Samurai-dokoro 141: 138: 79:banking system 26: 24: 14: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 437: 426: 423: 421: 418: 417: 415: 405: 404: 400: 397: 396: 392: 391: 387: 382: 378: 375: 371: 368: 364: 360: 359: 355: 353: 351: 347: 343: 339: 335: 331: 327: 323: 319: 311: 309: 307: 301: 298: 294: 289: 287: 283: 278: 274: 269: 267: 263: 259: 254: 249: 243: 238: 236: 235: 230: 225: 224: 219: 215: 213: 209: 204: 200: 199:clearinghouse 192: 190: 188: 183: 179: 177: 172: 166: 162: 160: 156: 152: 148: 139: 137: 135: 131: 126: 124: 120: 116: 109: 105: 101: 97: 93: 92: 87: 84: 80: 76: 72: 68: 64: 60: 53: 49: 44: 37: 32: 19: 401: 393: 380: 373: 362: 341: 337: 329: 321: 317: 315: 305: 302: 296: 292: 290: 272: 270: 265: 257: 252: 250: 241: 239: 234:sankin kƍtai 232: 228: 221: 217: 216: 196: 184: 180: 167: 163: 143: 133: 129: 127: 122: 107: 89: 88: 59:Rice brokers 58: 57: 18:Rice brokers 115:paper money 104:storehouses 414:Categories 356:References 151:Edo period 71:Edo period 350:Yoshiwara 348:theatre, 330:fudasashi 318:fudasashi 277:Confucian 182:periods. 100:Merchants 388:See also 187:ƌnin War 334:usurers 326:Asakusa 322:kuramae 306:daimyƍs 297:daimyƍs 293:daimyƍs 273:daimyƍs 266:daimyƍs 262:Genroku 258:daimyƍs 253:daimyƍs 229:daimyƍs 134:daimyƍs 130:daimyƍs 123:daimyƍs 91:Daimyƍs 69:in the 52:Hokusai 36:Hokusai 395:ton'ya 346:kabuki 342:chƍnin 338:daimyƍ 242:daimyƍ 218:Daimyƍ 212:guilds 108:daimyƍ 369:>. 245:' 208:Sakai 193:Osaka 159:Osaka 155:Kinai 147:Kyoto 140:Kyoto 119:loans 111:' 83:Kyoto 63:Osaka 48:Japan 223:koku 203:sake 96:rice 65:and 312:Edo 67:Edo 416:: 403:za 288:. 178:. 98:. 54:. 38:. 20:)

Index

Rice brokers

Hokusai

Japan
Hokusai
Osaka
Edo
Edo period
Japanese history
banking system
Kyoto
Daimyƍs
rice
Merchants
storehouses
paper money
loans
Kyoto
Edo period
Kinai
Osaka
Samurai-dokoro
Ashikaga Yoshimasa
ƌnin War
clearinghouse
sake
Sakai
guilds
koku

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑