Knowledge (XXG)

Marginal product

Source 📝

20: 361:, the marginal product initially increases when more of an input (say labor) is employed, keeping the other input (say capital) constant. Here, labor is the variable input and capital is the fixed input (in a hypothetical two-inputs model). As more and more of variable input (labor) is employed, marginal product starts to fall. Finally, after a certain point, the marginal product becomes negative, implying that the additional unit of labor has 411:
The relationship can be explained in three phases- (1) Initially, as the quantity of variable input is increased, TPP rises at an increasing rate. In this phase, MPP also rises. (2) As more and more quantities of the variable inputs are employed, TPP increases at a diminishing rate. In this phase,
47:) is the change in output resulting from employing one more unit of a particular input (for instance, the change in output when a firm's labor is increased from five to six units), assuming that the quantities of other inputs are kept constant. 569: 352: 300: 97: 403:, this proposition about the marginal product of capital cannot generally be sustained in multi-commodity models in which capital and consumption goods are distinguished. 229: 146: 123: 432: 166: 391:
wage. In aggregate models of perfect competition, in which a single good is produced and that good is used both in consumption and as a capital good, the
558: 175:
If the output and the input are infinitely divisible, so the marginal "units" are infinitesimal, the marginal product is the mathematical
412:
MPP starts to fall. (3) When the TPP reaches its maximum, MPP is zero. Beyond this point, TPP starts to fall and MPP becomes negative.
489: 582: 514: 366: 479: 601: 400: 388: 308: 256: 427: 392: 376:
curve, which is the production function plotted against labor usage for a fixed level of usage of the capital input.
56: 606: 148:
is the change in the quantity of output produced (resulting from the change in the input). Note that the quantity
422: 384: 548: 19: 32: 242:
are inputs to production (say, capital and labor, respectively). Then the marginal product of capital (
44: 380: 358: 180: 452: 578: 554: 510: 485: 442: 193: 128: 105: 571:
Classical Economics: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, Volume II
447: 396: 151: 595: 437: 373: 169: 125:
is the change in the firm's use of the input (conventionally a one-unit change) and
457: 365:
the output, rather than increasing it. The reason behind this is the diminishing
176: 16:
Change in output resulting from employing one more unit of a particular input
28: 407:
Relationship of marginal product (MPP) with the total product (TPP)
18: 505:
Mukherjee, Sampat; Mukherjee, Mallinath; Ghose, Amitava (2003).
23:
Average physical product (APP), marginal physical product (MPP)
50:
The marginal product of a given input can be expressed as:
481:
The Making of the Classical Theory of Economic Growth
311: 259: 196: 154: 131: 108: 59: 347:{\displaystyle MPL={\frac {\partial F}{\partial L}}} 295:{\displaystyle MPK={\frac {\partial F}{\partial K}}} 183:
with respect to that input. Suppose a firm's output
372:The marginal product of labor is the slope of the 346: 294: 223: 160: 140: 117: 91: 577:. Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute. 168:of the "product" is typically defined ignoring 92:{\displaystyle MP={\frac {\Delta Y}{\Delta X}}} 433:Marginal revenue productivity theory of wages 8: 531:Theory of Production: A Long-Period Analysis 529:Kurz, Heinz D. and Neri Salvadori (1995) 324: 310: 272: 258: 195: 153: 130: 107: 69: 58: 470: 509:. New Delhi: Prentice-Hall of India. 187:is given by the production function: 7: 553:. vdf, Hochsch.-Verlag an der ETH. 335: 327: 283: 275: 132: 109: 80: 72: 14: 246:) and marginal product of labor ( 379:In the neoclassical theory of 367:marginal productivity of labor 218: 206: 41:marginal physical productivity 1: 533:. Cambridge University Press. 401:Cambridge capital controversy 568:Rothbard, Murray N. (1995). 359:diminishing marginal returns 428:Marginal product of capital 393:marginal product of capital 170:external costs and benefits 625: 550:Volkswirtschaft verstehen 423:Marginal product of labor 385:marginal product of labor 478:Brewer, Anthony (2010). 224:{\displaystyle Y=F(K,L)} 141:{\displaystyle \Delta Y} 118:{\displaystyle \Delta X} 547:Beck, Bernhard (2008). 399:. As was shown in the 348: 296: 225: 162: 142: 119: 93: 33:neoclassical economics 24: 349: 297: 226: 163: 143: 120: 94: 22: 602:Production economics 309: 257: 194: 152: 129: 106: 57: 45:factor of production 381:competitive markets 181:production function 453:Cost of production 344: 292: 221: 158: 138: 115: 89: 31:and in particular 25: 607:Marginal concepts 560:978-3-7281-3207-9 443:Production theory 342: 290: 161:{\displaystyle Y} 87: 614: 588: 576: 564: 534: 527: 521: 520: 502: 496: 495: 475: 357:In the "law" of 353: 351: 350: 345: 343: 341: 333: 325: 301: 299: 298: 293: 291: 289: 281: 273: 250:) are given by: 230: 228: 227: 222: 167: 165: 164: 159: 147: 145: 144: 139: 124: 122: 121: 116: 98: 96: 95: 90: 88: 86: 78: 70: 37:marginal product 624: 623: 617: 616: 615: 613: 612: 611: 592: 591: 585: 574: 567: 561: 546: 543: 541:Further reading 538: 537: 528: 524: 517: 504: 503: 499: 492: 477: 476: 472: 467: 462: 448:Average product 418: 409: 334: 326: 307: 306: 282: 274: 255: 254: 192: 191: 150: 149: 127: 126: 104: 103: 79: 71: 55: 54: 17: 12: 11: 5: 622: 621: 618: 610: 609: 604: 594: 593: 590: 589: 583: 565: 559: 542: 539: 536: 535: 522: 515: 507:Microeconomics 497: 491:978-0415486200 490: 469: 468: 466: 463: 461: 460: 455: 450: 445: 440: 435: 430: 425: 419: 417: 414: 408: 405: 397:rate of return 355: 354: 340: 337: 332: 329: 323: 320: 317: 314: 303: 302: 288: 285: 280: 277: 271: 268: 265: 262: 232: 231: 220: 217: 214: 211: 208: 205: 202: 199: 157: 137: 134: 114: 111: 100: 99: 85: 82: 77: 74: 68: 65: 62: 15: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 620: 619: 608: 605: 603: 600: 599: 597: 586: 584:0-945466-48-X 580: 573: 572: 566: 562: 556: 552: 551: 545: 544: 540: 532: 526: 523: 518: 516:81-203-2318-1 512: 508: 501: 498: 493: 487: 484:. Routledge. 483: 482: 474: 471: 464: 459: 456: 454: 451: 449: 446: 444: 441: 439: 438:Marginal cost 436: 434: 431: 429: 426: 424: 421: 420: 415: 413: 406: 404: 402: 398: 394: 390: 386: 382: 377: 375: 374:total product 370: 368: 364: 360: 338: 330: 321: 318: 315: 312: 305: 304: 286: 278: 269: 266: 263: 260: 253: 252: 251: 249: 245: 241: 237: 215: 212: 209: 203: 200: 197: 190: 189: 188: 186: 182: 178: 173: 171: 155: 135: 112: 83: 75: 66: 63: 60: 53: 52: 51: 48: 46: 43:of an input ( 42: 38: 34: 30: 21: 570: 549: 530: 525: 506: 500: 480: 473: 458:Shadow price 410: 378: 371: 362: 356: 247: 243: 239: 235: 233: 184: 174: 101: 49: 40: 36: 26: 395:equals its 387:equals the 596:Categories 465:References 177:derivative 363:decreased 336:∂ 328:∂ 284:∂ 276:∂ 133:Δ 110:Δ 81:Δ 73:Δ 29:economics 416:See also 179:of the 581:  557:  513:  488:  383:, the 234:where 102:where 35:, the 575:(PDF) 579:ISBN 555:ISBN 511:ISBN 486:ISBN 389:real 238:and 248:MPL 244:MPK 39:or 27:In 598:: 369:. 172:. 587:. 563:. 519:. 494:. 339:L 331:F 322:= 319:L 316:P 313:M 287:K 279:F 270:= 267:K 264:P 261:M 240:L 236:K 219:) 216:L 213:, 210:K 207:( 204:F 201:= 198:Y 185:Y 156:Y 136:Y 113:X 84:X 76:Y 67:= 64:P 61:M

Index


economics
neoclassical economics
factor of production
external costs and benefits
derivative
production function
diminishing marginal returns
marginal productivity of labor
total product
competitive markets
marginal product of labor
real
marginal product of capital
rate of return
Cambridge capital controversy
Marginal product of labor
Marginal product of capital
Marginal revenue productivity theory of wages
Marginal cost
Production theory
Average product
Cost of production
Shadow price
The Making of the Classical Theory of Economic Growth
ISBN
978-0415486200
ISBN
81-203-2318-1
Volkswirtschaft verstehen

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.