Knowledge (XXG)

Altruism theory of voting

Source 📝

998:
the poorer half, and the redistribution created no overall effects, a voter under the broad altruism model would have no incentive to vote. However, if a voter cared particularly for the welfare of the poor, that voter would have an incentive to vote for the candidate; similarly, a voter that cared particular for the welfare of the rich would have an incentive to vote against the candidate. The result in my model is that both such voters would be rationally motivated to vote.
633: 951:" as an explanation for why the average voter holds views that are persistently and systematically contradictory to the consensus view of expert economists. His thesis is that indulging innate cognitive biases (of which he identifies four as being major contributors to bad economic policy positions) is psychologically gratifying, while overcoming natural prejudices through training, education, and 862:...There is by now a substantial literature in economics, sociology, biology, psychology, and political science yielding evidence that human beings are also motivated by the welfare of others (Fehr and Fischbacher 2003; Monroe 1998; Piliavin and Charng 1990). Specifically, people frequently engage in acts of altruism by choosing to bear costs in order to provide benefits to others. 793:, the probability of any one vote determining the outcome, is extremely small for any large election, the expected benefits of voting under the traditional rational choice model is always roughly equal to zero. This leads to the so-called paradox of voting, in which rational choice models of voter behavior predict tiny turnouts which simply do not occur. In all democracies, 36: 871:... or an individual with both selfish and social preferences, the social preferences will dominate and make it rational for a typical person to vote even in large elections;(2) to show that rational socially-motivated voting has a feedback mechanism that stabilizes turnout at reasonable levels (e.g., 50% of the electorate)... 851:
Scholars incorporate altruism into the traditional calculus of voting model by assuming that a citizen also cares about the benefits that others secure from the preferred outcome (Edlin, Gelman, and Kaplan 2006; Jankowski 2002, 2004). Under this assumption, B is a function not only of direct benefits
839:
Because of the multitude of different and contradictory definitions of expressive voting, recently another effort by political scientists and public choice theorists has been made to explain voting behavior with reference to instrumental benefits received from influencing the outcome of the election.
997:
It is rational to vote as long as the candidates differ in their effect on the welfare of subsets of the population, and one happens to be particularly concerned with an affected subset. For example, if a candidate proposed to take wealth from the richer half of the population and distribute it to
866:
Essentially, voters behave altruistically by absorbing the cost of voting in order to provide society with the benefits of their preferred policy, although the expected reward of voting under this model is greater than zero (and thus still a rational decision) because of voters' altruistic social
962:
These views tend not to be related to the particular voter in any rationally self-interested way, and so voters are genuinely not being subject to any direct economic penalties for choosing irrational policies. The altruistic voter will indulge, without restraint, in make-work bias, anti-foreign
831:, intended to actually change the outcome. The benefits here did not come from actually influencing the election, but rather from the social payoffs of participating in it. Because the term BP was assumed to be zero, D was presumed to be the only important factor in determining elections. 972:
A 2008 study of voters in Sweden during the 1990s found significant evidence for self-interested "pocketbook" voting. The authors found that voters can and will respond to direct promises of personal economic benefits, although it appears that citizens respond almost entirely to the
840:
If voters assumed to be rational but also to have altruistic tendencies and some preference for outcomes enhancing the social welfare of others, they will reliably vote in favor of the policies they perceive to be for the common good, rather than for their individual benefit.
852:
to oneself BS, but to the N other people affected by the outcome of the election who would gain an average benefit BO if the citizen’s preferred alternative won. It also depends on how much the citizen cares about benefits to others, which is labeled a for altruism.
785:
is the individual's expected reward from voting. If R > 0, then the expected utility of voting outweighs its costs, and it is reasonable to vote. But if R ≤ 0, the costs outweigh the benefits and a strictly rational individual would not be expected to vote.
898:
argued that, all else equal, voters do not, in fact, choose policies based on self-interest. The rich are not more likely to support policies that personally benefit them, like lower marginal rates, and the poor are not more likely to oppose welfare reform.
922:
Wrong, wrong, wrong. The 47% won't vote for Obama "no matter what." Almost half of voters who earn less than the median income vote Republican in the typical election. A person doesn't support the nanny state because he wants government to take care of
984:
George Mason Law Professor Tun-Jen Chiang criticized the Edlin altruist model as overly simplistic and ultimately naive about voter preferences. Chiang presents an alternative model of altruist voting behavior, centered around voters'
989:
altruism towards favored racial, cultural, religious, regional, sexual, economic, or social groups (of which they may or may not be a member). He contends that, even if two candidates policies had identical social welfare benefits
886: 875:
Their findings suggest that in a large election, altruistic preferences will trump selfish tendencies, thus encouraging a stable voter turnout that closely mirrors the observed rate in western democracies.
691:
from helping others, to vote. Altruistic voting has been compared to purchasing a lottery ticket, in which the probability of winning is extremely low but the payoff is large enough that the
687:
will be outweighed by the large cumulative benefits society will receive from the voter's preferred policy being enacted, such that it is rational for an “altruistic” citizen, who receives
935:
Caplan says that voters consistently demonstrate preferences that are not clearly related to self-interest, and they are motivated primarily by what they believe is best for the country.
902:
He claims that what he calls the "Self-Interest Voter Hypothesis" (SIVH), the theory that individuals' policy preferences are narrowly selfish, is empirically wrong. In response to U.S.
955:, is psychologically costly. Therefore, when the personal benefit giving in to our biases is greater than the personal cost suffered from acting on them, individuals will tend to 805:
Because simple selfishness cannot explain why large numbers of people consistently choose to vote, Riker and Ordeshook introduced another term to the equation,
683:
which states that if citizens in a democracy have "social" preferences for the welfare of others, the extremely low probability of a single vote determining an
353: 1143:
Caplan, Bryan. "Will False Belief in the SIVH Destroy Romney's Candidacy?" EconLog. Library of Economics and Liberty, 18 Sept. 2012. Web. 20 Oct. 2012.
318: 348: 187: 290: 745: 809:, to symbolize the personal or social benefits conferred by the act of voting itself, rather than by affecting the outcome of the election. 493: 959:
indulge in irrational behavior, like voting for protectionist tariffs and other economically damaging but socially popular policies.
714:
as a way to explain why rational individuals would choose to vote despite its apparent lack of individual benefit, explaining the
903: 661: 722:
of elections in favor of the candidate that they believe will implement policies for the greater good of the entire population.
338: 1185: 615: 275: 1115: 266: 911: 295: 232: 488: 247: 963:
bias, pessimistic bias, and anti-market bias, all in the hopes of better his fellow man through the ballot box.
323: 1071:"Buying a Lottery Ticket to Help the Poor: Altruism, Civic Duty, and Self-interest in the Decision to Vote." 891: 309: 1195: 1169:
George Mason University Law and Economics Research Paper Series. 12–36 (2012): n. page. Web. 22 Oct. 2012.
1027: 948: 503: 404: 285: 952: 358: 343: 242: 718:. The theory suggests that individual voters do, in fact, derive personal utility from influencing the 654: 399: 1156:
Institute for the Study of Labor Discussion Paper Series. 3763 (2008): n. page. Web. 22 Oct. 2012.
1190: 1022: 944: 610: 569: 159: 144: 98: 93: 66: 1012: 823: 715: 579: 559: 498: 447: 328: 280: 214: 139: 129: 108: 103: 20: 736: 513: 442: 394: 237: 223: 1058:"Voting as a Rational Choice: Why and How People Vote To Improve the Well-Being of Others." 1032: 1017: 844: 740: 699: 680: 647: 637: 564: 547: 483: 409: 363: 61: 508: 452: 257: 252: 197: 192: 867:
preferences. Edlin, et al., found in their study of altruistic behavior among voters,
632: 1179: 1037: 915: 794: 707: 703: 605: 523: 518: 178: 154: 149: 71: 1102:
The American Political Science Review 62.1 (1968): 25–42. JSTOR. Web. 20 Nov. 2012.
895: 600: 584: 532: 423: 414: 389: 169: 134: 1099: 1086: 927:; a person supports the nanny state because he wants government to take care of 907: 574: 457: 437: 164: 1070: 1118:
British Journal of Political Science. 41.3 (2011): 645–670. Web. 22 Oct. 2012.
432: 300: 124: 84: 1073:
Rationality and Society 14.1 (2002): 55–77. Sage Journals. Web. 20 Oct. 2012.
80: 1057: 827:, intended only to signal support or demonstrate civic responsibility, and 749:. The basic utility hypothesis for the calculus of voting they gave was: 711: 684: 333: 688: 1116:"Expressive Political Behaviour: Foundations, Scope and Implications." 1089:
The Journal of Politics 68.3 (2006): 673–83. JSTOR. Web. 20 Oct. 2012.
35: 847:
explained how the altruistic theory modified the calculus of voting:
52: 27: 1166: 1154:"Selfish and Prospective: Theory and Evidence of Pocketbook Voting." 1132:
The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies
887:
The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies
914:
who will "always" vote Democrat because they are dependent on the
1060:
Rationality and Society. 19.3 (2008): 293–314. Web. 22 Oct. 2012.
702:
models—which assume voters have "selfish" preferences—to explain
1153: 1131: 743:
in their 1968 article "A Theory of the Calculus of Voting" in
777:(that is, turning the election for his preferred candidate); 710:
economists and social scientists have increasingly turned to
781:
is the individual's cost of voting in the election; and
735:
The standard model of voter calculus was articulated by
797:
exceeds what the basic rational choice models predict.
855:
These assumptions transform the calculus of voting to
1152:
Elinder, Mikael, Henrik Jordahl, and Panu Poutvaara.
981:to the actual implementation of those policies. 773:is the probability of the voter bringing about 769:receives from his preferred candidate winning; 1056:Edlin, Aaron, Andrew Gelman, and Noah Kaplan. 765:is the expected differential utility a voter 655: 8: 364:Parallel voting (Mixed member majoritarian) 1167:"Unequal Altruism and the Voting Paradox." 1134:, Princeton University Press, 2007. Print. 662: 648: 553: 477: 383: 329:Mixed single vote (positive vote transfer) 267:Proportional and semi-proportional systems 219: 48: 15: 1126: 1124: 1110: 1108: 1098:Riker, William H., and Peter Ordeshook. 1081: 1079: 943:Related to the public choice concept of 1049: 592: 531: 422: 308: 265: 222: 177: 116: 79: 51: 26: 879: 1100:"A Theory of the Calculus of Voting." 843:In his paper "Altruism and Turnout," 835:The "altruistic" rationale for voting 801:Expressive versus instrumental voting 746:The American Political Science Review 7: 1114:Hamlin, Alan, and Colin Jennings. 947:, Caplan proposes the concept of " 731:The "selfish" rationale for voting 224:Plurality and majoritarian systems 14: 334:Scorporo (negative vote transfer) 821:This drew a distinction between 631: 34: 726:The rational calculus of voting 880:Voter's altruistic preferences 698:Since the failure of standard 339:Mixed ballot transferable vote 1: 967:Criticisms and modifications 695:benefit outweighs the cost. 616:End-to-end verifiable voting 276:Single non-transferable vote 474:Voting patterns and effects 1212: 296:Single transferable voting 233:First-past-the-post voting 677:altruism theory of voting 489:Voting advice application 319:Mixed-member proportional 248:Plurality-at-large voting 354:Rural–urban proportional 349:Dual-member proportional 324:Additional member system 1087:"Altruism and Turnout." 892:George Mason University 1028:Rational irrationality 949:rational irrationality 939:Rational irrationality 912:the "47%" of Americans 504:Passive electioneering 405:Straight-ticket voting 359:Majority bonus system 344:Alternative Vote Plus 243:Instant-runoff voting 1186:Public choice theory 1069:Jankowski, Richard. 975:prospective promises 706:in large elections, 310:Mixed-member systems 977:of politicians but 857:P(BS + aNBO) > C 829:instrumental voting 638:Politics portal 400:Split-ticket voting 1023:Rational ignorance 945:rational ignorance 611:Voter registration 570:Voter intimidation 94:Write-in candidate 67:Provisional ballot 1165:Chiang, Tun-Jen. 1085:Fowler, James H. 1013:Paradox of voting 918:, Caplan writes, 910:'s remarks about 884:In his 2007 book 824:expressive voting 716:paradox of voting 672: 671: 623: 622: 580:Voter suppression 560:Ballot harvesting 538: 537: 499:Paradox of voting 465: 464: 448:None of the above 380:Voting strategies 371: 370: 281:Cumulative voting 215:Electoral systems 205: 204: 140:Electronic voting 130:Compulsory voting 1203: 1170: 1163: 1157: 1150: 1144: 1141: 1135: 1128: 1119: 1112: 1103: 1096: 1090: 1083: 1074: 1067: 1061: 1054: 815:R = (BP) − C + D 664: 657: 650: 636: 635: 554: 514:Political apathy 478: 443:Election boycott 384: 238:Two-round system 220: 49: 38: 16: 1211: 1210: 1206: 1205: 1204: 1202: 1201: 1200: 1176: 1175: 1174: 1173: 1164: 1160: 1151: 1147: 1142: 1138: 1129: 1122: 1113: 1106: 1097: 1093: 1084: 1077: 1068: 1064: 1055: 1051: 1046: 1033:Voting behavior 1018:Rational choice 1009: 969: 941: 882: 845:James H. Fowler 837: 817: 803: 757: 733: 728: 700:rational choice 674: 668: 630: 625: 624: 565:Ballot stuffing 551: 548:Electoral fraud 540: 539: 484:Coattail effect 475: 467: 466: 410:Tactical voting 381: 373: 372: 286:Binomial system 217: 207: 206: 85:Ballot measures 62:Absentee ballot 46: 21:Politics series 12: 11: 5: 1209: 1207: 1199: 1198: 1193: 1188: 1178: 1177: 1172: 1171: 1158: 1145: 1136: 1130:Bryan Caplan. 1120: 1104: 1091: 1075: 1062: 1048: 1047: 1045: 1042: 1041: 1040: 1035: 1030: 1025: 1020: 1015: 1008: 1005: 1004: 1003: 1001: 1000: 999: 992: 991: 982: 968: 965: 940: 937: 933: 932: 881: 878: 873: 872: 864: 863: 860: 853: 836: 833: 819: 818: 813: 802: 799: 759: 758: 753: 732: 729: 727: 724: 681:voter behavior 679:is a model of 670: 669: 667: 666: 659: 652: 644: 641: 640: 627: 626: 621: 620: 619: 618: 613: 608: 603: 595: 594: 590: 589: 588: 587: 582: 577: 572: 567: 562: 552: 550:and prevention 546: 545: 542: 541: 536: 535: 529: 528: 527: 526: 521: 516: 511: 509:Vote splitting 506: 501: 496: 491: 486: 476: 473: 472: 469: 468: 463: 462: 461: 460: 455: 453:Refused ballot 450: 445: 440: 435: 427: 426: 420: 419: 418: 417: 412: 407: 402: 397: 392: 382: 379: 378: 375: 374: 369: 368: 367: 366: 361: 356: 351: 346: 341: 336: 331: 326: 321: 313: 312: 306: 305: 304: 303: 298: 293: 288: 283: 278: 270: 269: 263: 262: 261: 260: 258:Usual judgment 255: 253:General ticket 250: 245: 240: 235: 227: 226: 218: 213: 212: 209: 208: 203: 202: 201: 200: 198:Voting machine 195: 190: 182: 181: 175: 174: 173: 172: 167: 162: 157: 152: 147: 142: 137: 132: 127: 119: 118: 114: 113: 112: 111: 106: 101: 96: 88: 87: 77: 76: 75: 74: 69: 64: 56: 55: 47: 44: 43: 40: 39: 31: 30: 24: 23: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 1208: 1197: 1196:Voting theory 1194: 1192: 1189: 1187: 1184: 1183: 1181: 1168: 1162: 1159: 1155: 1149: 1146: 1140: 1137: 1133: 1127: 1125: 1121: 1117: 1111: 1109: 1105: 1101: 1095: 1092: 1088: 1082: 1080: 1076: 1072: 1066: 1063: 1059: 1053: 1050: 1043: 1039: 1038:Voting system 1036: 1034: 1031: 1029: 1026: 1024: 1021: 1019: 1016: 1014: 1011: 1010: 1006: 1002: 996: 995: 994: 993: 988: 983: 980: 976: 971: 970: 966: 964: 960: 958: 954: 950: 946: 938: 936: 930: 926: 921: 920: 919: 917: 916:welfare state 913: 909: 905: 900: 897: 893: 889: 888: 877: 870: 869: 868: 861: 858: 854: 850: 849: 848: 846: 841: 834: 832: 830: 826: 825: 816: 812: 811: 810: 808: 800: 798: 796: 795:voter turnout 792: 787: 784: 780: 776: 772: 768: 764: 756: 752: 751: 750: 748: 747: 742: 738: 730: 725: 723: 721: 717: 713: 709: 708:public choice 705: 704:voter turnout 701: 696: 694: 690: 686: 682: 678: 665: 660: 658: 653: 651: 646: 645: 643: 642: 639: 634: 629: 628: 617: 614: 612: 609: 607: 606:Secret ballot 604: 602: 599: 598: 597: 596: 591: 586: 583: 581: 578: 576: 573: 571: 568: 566: 563: 561: 558: 557: 556: 555: 549: 544: 543: 534: 533:Protest votes 530: 525: 524:Voter turnout 522: 520: 519:Voter fatigue 517: 515: 512: 510: 507: 505: 502: 500: 497: 495: 492: 490: 487: 485: 482: 481: 480: 479: 471: 470: 459: 456: 454: 451: 449: 446: 444: 441: 439: 436: 434: 431: 430: 429: 428: 425: 424:Protest votes 421: 416: 413: 411: 408: 406: 403: 401: 398: 396: 395:Fusion voting 393: 391: 388: 387: 386: 385: 377: 376: 365: 362: 360: 357: 355: 352: 350: 347: 345: 342: 340: 337: 335: 332: 330: 327: 325: 322: 320: 317: 316: 315: 314: 311: 307: 302: 299: 297: 294: 292: 289: 287: 284: 282: 279: 277: 274: 273: 272: 271: 268: 264: 259: 256: 254: 251: 249: 246: 244: 241: 239: 236: 234: 231: 230: 229: 228: 225: 221: 216: 211: 210: 199: 196: 194: 191: 189: 186: 185: 184: 183: 180: 176: 171: 168: 166: 163: 161: 158: 156: 155:Postal voting 153: 151: 150:Polling place 148: 146: 143: 141: 138: 136: 133: 131: 128: 126: 123: 122: 121: 120: 115: 110: 107: 105: 102: 100: 97: 95: 92: 91: 90: 89: 86: 82: 78: 73: 72:Sample ballot 70: 68: 65: 63: 60: 59: 58: 57: 54: 50: 42: 41: 37: 33: 32: 29: 25: 22: 18: 17: 1161: 1148: 1139: 1094: 1065: 1052: 986: 978: 974: 961: 956: 942: 934: 928: 924: 901: 896:Bryan Caplan 885: 883: 874: 865: 856: 842: 838: 828: 822: 820: 814: 806: 804: 790: 788: 782: 778: 774: 770: 766: 762: 760: 755:R = (BP) − C 754: 744: 734: 719: 697: 692: 676: 673: 601:Election ink 585:Voter caging 494:Likely voter 415:Vote pairing 390:Issue voting 188:Popular vote 170:Voting booth 135:Early voting 19:Part of the 908:Mitt Romney 575:Vote buying 458:Spoilt vote 438:Donkey vote 165:Vote center 145:Open ballot 1180:Categories 1044:References 957:rationally 953:skepticism 906:candidate 904:Republican 894:economist 767:personally 593:Prevention 433:Abstention 301:Spare vote 291:Party-list 125:Ballot box 117:Collection 99:Electorate 81:Candidates 1191:Elections 987:selective 741:Ordeshook 45:Balloting 1007:See also 990:overall, 789:Because 712:altruism 693:expected 685:election 179:Counting 160:Precinct 720:outcome 689:utility 53:Ballots 761:Where 109:Ticket 28:Voting 737:Riker 193:Tally 104:Slate 739:and 675:The 83:and 979:not 925:him 1182:: 1123:^ 1107:^ 1078:^ 929:us 890:, 931:. 859:. 807:D 791:P 783:R 779:C 775:B 771:P 763:B 663:e 656:t 649:v

Index

Politics series
Voting

Ballots
Absentee ballot
Provisional ballot
Sample ballot
Candidates
Ballot measures
Write-in candidate
Electorate
Slate
Ticket
Ballot box
Compulsory voting
Early voting
Electronic voting
Open ballot
Polling place
Postal voting
Precinct
Vote center
Voting booth
Counting
Popular vote
Tally
Voting machine
Electoral systems
Plurality and majoritarian systems
First-past-the-post voting

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑