Knowledge (XXG)

Deadweight loss

Source đź“ť

267:, a tax levied against goods deemed harmful to society and individuals. For example, "sin taxes" levied against alcohol and tobacco are intended to artificially lower demand for these goods; some would-be users are priced out of the market, i.e. total smoking and drinking are reduced. Products such as alcohol and tobacco have historically been highly taxed and incur excise duties which are one of the categories of indirect tax. Indirect tax (VAT), weighs on the consumer, is not a cause of loss of surplus for the producer, but affects consumer utility and leads to deadweight loss for consumers. Indirect taxes are usually paid by large entities such as corporations or manufacturers but are partially shifted towards the consumer. Furthermore, indirect taxes can be charged based on the unit price of a said commodity or can be calculated based on a percentage of the final retail price. Additionally, indirect taxes can either be collected at one stage of the production and retail process or alternatively can be charged and collected at multiple stages of the overall production process of a commodity. 148:(to society) – in other words, there are either goods being produced despite the cost of doing so being larger than the benefit, or additional goods are not being produced despite the fact that the benefits of their production would be larger than the costs. The deadweight loss is the net benefit that is missed out on. While losses to one entity often lead to gains for another, deadweight loss represents the loss that is not regained by anyone else. This loss is therefore attributed to both producers and consumers. 152: 1596: 376:, the maximum amount that a taxpayer would be willing to forgo in a lump sum to avoid the tax. The deadweight loss can then be interpreted as the difference between the equivalent variation and the revenue raised by the tax. The difference is attributable to the behavioral changes induced by a distortionary tax that are measured by the substitution effect. However, that is not the only interpretation, and 642:
minimally to changes in the price. However, when the supply curve is more elastic, quantity supplied responds significantly to changes in price. In other words, when the supply curve is more elastic, the area between the supply and demand curves is larger. Similarly, when the demand curve is relatively inelastic, deadweight loss from the tax is smaller, comparing to more elastic demand curve.
25: 1585: 389: 276: 505:
decreases. Therefore, buyers and sellers share the burden of the tax, regardless of how it is imposed. Since a tax places a "wedge" between the price buyers pay and the price sellers get, the quantity sold is reduced below the level that it would be without tax. To put it another way, a tax on a good causes the size of market for that good to decrease.
664:
However, when a much higher tax is levied, tax revenue eventually decreases. The higher tax reduces the total size of the market; Although taxes are taking a larger slice of the "pie", the total size of the pie is reduced. Just as in the nail example above, beyond a certain point, the market for a good will eventually decrease to zero.
250:
actually still costs $ 0.10 per nail. Consumers with a marginal benefit of between $ 0.07 and $ 0.10 per nail would then buy nails, even though their benefit is less than the real production cost of $ 0.10. The difference between the cost of production and the purchase price then creates the "deadweight loss" to society.
520:
Government revenue is also affected by this tax: since Amie and Will have abandoned the deal, the government also loses any tax revenue that would have resulted from wages. This $ 40 is referred to as the deadweight loss. It causes losses for both buyers and sellers in a market, as well as decreasing
516:
However, if the government were to decide to impose a $ 50 tax upon the providers of cleaning services, their trade would no longer benefit them. Amie would not be willing to pay any price above $ 120, and Will would no longer receive a payment that exceeds his opportunity cost. As a result, not only
236:
producer of this product would typically charge whatever price will yield the greatest profit for themselves, regardless of lost efficiency for the economy as a whole. In this example, the monopoly producer charges $ 0.60 per nail, thus excluding every customer from the market with a marginal benefit
645:
A tax results in deadweight loss as it causes buyers and sellers to change their behaviour. Buyers tend to consume less when the tax raises the price. When the tax lowers the price received by sellers, they in turn produce less. As a result, the overall size of the market decreases below the optimum
517:
do Amie and Will both give up the deal, but Amie has to live in a dirtier house, and Will does not receive his desired income. They have thus lost amount of the surplus that they would have received from their deal, and at the same time, this made each of them worse off to the tune of $ 40 in value.
659:
than the tax itself; the area of the triangle representing the deadweight loss is calculated using the area (square) of its dimension. Where a tax increases linearly, the deadweight loss increases as the square of the tax increase. This means that when the size of a tax doubles, the base and height
524:
In the graph, the deadweight loss can be seen as the shaded area between the supply and demand curves. While the demand curve shows the value of goods to the consumers, the supply curve reflects the cost for producers. As the example above explains, when the government imposes a tax upon taxpayers,
672:
A deadweight loss occurs with monopolies in the same way that a tax causes deadweight loss. When a monopoly, as a "tax collector", charges a price in order to consolidate its power above marginal cost, it drives a "wedge" between the costs born by the consumer and supplier. Imposing this effective
641:
Price elasticities of supply and demand determine whether the deadweight loss from a tax is large or small. This measures to what extent quantity supplied and quantity demanded respond to changes in price. For instance, when the supply curve is relatively inelastic, quantity supplied responds only
663:
The varying deadweight loss from a tax also affects the government's total tax revenue. Tax revenue is represented by the area of the rectangle between the supply and demand curves. When a low tax is levied, tax revenue is relatively small. As the size of the tax increases, tax revenue expands.
258:
A tax has the opposite effect of a subsidy. Whereas a subsidy entices consumers to buy a product that would otherwise be too expensive for them in light of their marginal benefit (price is lowered to artificially increase demand), a tax dissuades consumers from a purchase (price is increased to
249:
of a product than they otherwise would based on their marginal benefit and the cost of production. For example, if in the same nail market the government provided a $ 0.03 subsidy for every nail produced, the subsidy would reduce the market price of each nail to $ 0.07, even though production
504:
When a tax is levied on buyers, the demand curve shifts downward in accordance with the size of the tax. Similarly, when tax is levied on sellers, the supply curve shifts upward by the size of tax. When the tax is imposed, the price paid by buyers increases, and the price received by seller
237:
less than $ 0.60. The deadweight loss due to monopoly pricing would then be the economic benefit foregone by customers with a marginal benefit of between $ 0.10 and $ 0.60 per nail. The monopolist has "priced them out of the market", even though their benefit exceeds the true cost per nail.
309:
The area represented by the triangle results from the fact that the intersection of the supply and the demand curves are cut short. The consumer surplus and the producer surplus are also cut short. The loss of such surplus is never recouped and represents the deadweight loss.
654:
Taxes may be changed by the government or policymakers at different levels. For instance, when a low tax is levied, the deadweight loss is also small (compared to a medium or high tax). An important consideration is that the deadweight loss resulting from a tax increases
215:
Assume a market for nails where the cost of each nail is $ 0.10. Demand decreases linearly; there is a high demand for free nails and zero demand for nails at a price per nail of $ 1.10 or higher. The price of $ 0.10 per nail represents the point of
512:
of Will's time is $ 80, while the value of a clean house to Amie is $ 120. Hence, each of them get same amount of benefit from their deal. Amie and Will each receive a benefit of $ 20, making the total surplus from trade $ 40.
646:
equilibrium. The elasticities of supply and demand determine to what extent the tax distorts the market outcome. As the elasticities of supply and demand increase, so does the deadweight loss resulting from a tax.
279:
The deadweight loss is the area of the triangle bounded by the right edge of the grey tax income box, the original supply curve, and the demand curve. It is called Harberger's triangle.
677:. It is important to remember the difference between the two cases: whereas the government receives the revenue from a genuine tax, monopoly profits are collected by a private firm. 287:, shows the deadweight loss (as measured on a supply and demand graph) associated with government intervention in a perfect market. Mechanisms for this intervention include 631: 604: 577: 550: 498: 471: 444: 417: 508:
For example, suppose that Will is a cleaner who is working in the cleaning service company and Amie hired Will to clean her room every week for $ 100. The
1466: 965: 306:
between what consumers pay and what producers receive, and the area of this wedge shape is equivalent to the deadweight loss caused by the tax.
192: 938: 864: 795: 521:
government revenues. Taxes cause deadweight losses because they prevent buyers and sellers from realizing some of the gains from trade.
372:
In modern economic literature, the most common measure of a taxpayer's loss from a distortionary tax, such as a tax on bicycles, is the
361:
and noted that when the Marshallian demand curve is perfectly inelastic, the policy or economic situation that caused a distortion in
108: 295:, taxes, tariffs, or quotas. It also refers to the deadweight loss created by a government's failure to intervene in a market with 167:
may or may not increase; however, the decrease in producer surplus must be greater than the increase, if any, in consumer surplus.
883: 42: 89: 1620: 579:. Buyers and sellers (Amie and Will) give up the deal between them and exit the market. Thus, the quantity sold reduces from 46: 61: 1157: 232:, producers would charge a price of $ 0.10, and every customer whose marginal benefit exceeds $ 0.10 would buy a nail. A 958: 68: 1451: 1403: 1091: 342: 1635: 1113: 1101: 1096: 1086: 1056: 35: 1531: 1007: 686: 260: 75: 1197: 1066: 334: 1625: 1599: 1496: 1491: 1441: 1314: 1192: 951: 57: 1516: 1476: 1471: 1253: 1224: 1081: 1003: 354: 1461: 1446: 1162: 321:
by pivoting the trend downwards and causing a magnification of losses in the long run but others like
1511: 1431: 1363: 1278: 1172: 1108: 373: 217: 122: 633:. The deadweight loss occurs because the tax deters these kinds of beneficial trades in the market. 1526: 1353: 1202: 1145: 988: 765: 366: 358: 353:
is considered, it can be shown that the Marshallian deadweight loss is zero if demand is perfectly
229: 184: 172: 1436: 1382: 1309: 1219: 1177: 1167: 1135: 1130: 1076: 1071: 747: 673:
tax distorts the market outcome, and the wedge causes a decrease in the quantity sold, below the
380:
did not use a lump sum tax as the point of reference to discuss deadweight loss (excess burden).
377: 318: 151: 660:
of the triangle double. Thus, doubling the tax increases the deadweight loss by a factor of 4.
1630: 1569: 1557: 1536: 1506: 1368: 1292: 1248: 860: 791: 701: 82: 1521: 1501: 1408: 1358: 1329: 1187: 1152: 1049: 1027: 918: 892: 739: 509: 350: 314: 284: 176: 164: 160: 141: 137: 609: 582: 555: 528: 476: 449: 422: 395: 1589: 998: 346: 939:
Worthwhile Canadian Initiative "Too much stuff: the deadweight loss from overconsumption"
263:
represents the lost utility for the consumer. A common example of this is the so-called
1564: 1304: 1263: 1182: 974: 691: 362: 923: 906: 1614: 1486: 1386: 1377: 1348: 1334: 1324: 1268: 1032: 1022: 1012: 751: 292: 196: 156: 145: 1456: 1288: 1283: 1017: 848: 727: 204: 1481: 1393: 1273: 1125: 1039: 696: 674: 357:
or supply is perfectly inelastic. However, Hicks analyzed the situation through
322: 296: 288: 200: 188: 24: 392:
The deadweight loss of taxation; the tax increases the price paid by buyers to
1241: 993: 743: 706: 338: 1552: 1319: 1236: 1231: 1044: 388: 303: 129: 1584: 1344: 1339: 1214: 896: 852: 233: 180: 1398: 1297: 1209: 875: 728:"Optimal Concentration and Deadweight Losses in Canadian Manufacturing" 275: 264: 179:
or a service is not produced. Non-optimal production can be caused by
1373: 1258: 1140: 1120: 943: 245:
Conversely, deadweight loss can also arise from consumers buying
1415: 325:
have argued that they do not have a huge impact on the economy.
302:
In the case of a government tax, the amount of the tax drives a
947: 18: 317:
maintain that these triangles can seriously affect long-term
140:
due to production/consumption of a good at a quantity where
349:) demand function differ about deadweight loss. After the 612: 585: 558: 531: 479: 452: 425: 398: 1545: 1424: 981: 49:. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. 625: 598: 571: 544: 492: 465: 438: 411: 525:the tax increases the price paid by buyers to 283:Harberger's triangle, generally attributed to 171:Deadweight loss can also be a measure of lost 959: 8: 552:and decreases price received by sellers to 419:and decreases price received by sellers to 966: 952: 944: 121:"DWL" redirects here. For other uses, see 922: 650:How deadweight loss changes as taxes vary 617: 611: 590: 584: 563: 557: 536: 530: 484: 478: 457: 451: 430: 424: 403: 397: 109:Learn how and when to remove this message 907:"A Note on the Concept of Excess Burden" 387: 274: 175:when the socially optimal quantity of a 150: 718: 155:Deadweight loss created by a binding 7: 876:"Three Sides of Harberger Triangles" 824: 822: 820: 818: 816: 47:adding citations to reliable sources 726:Dickson, Vaughan; He, Jian (1997). 446:and the quantity sold reduces from 16:Measure of lost economic efficiency 1522:Microfoundations of macroeconomics 14: 833:. South-Western Cengage Learning. 732:Review of Industrial Organization 259:artificially lower demand). This 1595: 1594: 1583: 905:Lind, H.; Granqvist, R. (2010). 884:Journal of Economic Perspectives 788:Public Finance and Public Policy 23: 859:(5th ed.). Prentice-Hall. 637:Determinants of deadweight loss 34:needs additional citations for 829:N. Mankiw-David Hakes (2012). 790:. New York: Worth Publishers. 1: 924:10.1016/S0313-5926(10)50004-3 668:Deadweight loss of a monopoly 369:, i.e. is a deadweight loss. 911:Economic Analysis and Policy 874:Hines, James R. Jr. (1999). 831:Principles of microeconomics 144:(to society) does not equal 1467:Civil engineering economics 1452:Statistical decision theory 1092:Income elasticity of demand 1652: 1102:Price elasticity of supply 1097:Price elasticity of demand 1087:Cross elasticity of demand 163:always decreases, but the 120: 1578: 810:Lind and Granqvist (2010) 786:Gruber, Jonathan (2013). 687:Excess burden of taxation 261:excess burden of taxation 228:If market conditions are 220:in a competitive market. 187:, a positive or negative 1158:Income–consumption curve 270: 136:is the loss of societal 1492:Industrial organization 857:Principles of Economics 744:10.1023/A:1007714502964 183:pricing in the case of 766:"Negative Externality" 627: 600: 573: 546: 501: 494: 467: 440: 413: 280: 168: 1621:Imperfect competition 1462:Engineering economics 1057:Cost–benefit analysis 628: 626:{\displaystyle Q_{t}} 601: 599:{\displaystyle Q_{e}} 574: 572:{\displaystyle P_{p}} 547: 545:{\displaystyle P_{c}} 495: 493:{\displaystyle Q_{t}} 468: 466:{\displaystyle Q_{e}} 441: 439:{\displaystyle P_{p}} 414: 412:{\displaystyle P_{c}} 391: 313:Some economists like 278: 154: 1279:Price discrimination 1173:Intertemporal choice 897:10.1257/jep.13.2.167 610: 583: 556: 529: 477: 450: 423: 396: 374:equivalent variation 271:Harberger's triangle 218:economic equilibrium 123:DWL (disambiguation) 43:improve this article 1590:Business portal 1527:Operations research 1354:Substitution effect 367:substitution effect 359:indifference curves 230:perfect competition 185:artificial scarcity 173:economic efficiency 1168:Indifference curve 1136:Goods and services 1077:Economies of scope 1072:Economies of scale 623: 596: 569: 542: 502: 490: 463: 436: 409: 329:Hicks vs. Marshall 281: 169: 1636:Welfare economics 1608: 1607: 1570:Political economy 1369:Supply and demand 1249:Pareto efficiency 866:978-0-13-961905-2 797:978-1-4292-7845-4 702:Pareto efficiency 119: 118: 111: 93: 58:"Deadweight loss" 1643: 1598: 1597: 1588: 1587: 1330:Returns to scale 1188:Market structure 968: 961: 954: 945: 928: 926: 900: 880: 870: 835: 834: 826: 811: 808: 802: 801: 783: 777: 776: 774: 772: 762: 756: 755: 738:(5/6): 719–732. 723: 632: 630: 629: 624: 622: 621: 605: 603: 602: 597: 595: 594: 578: 576: 575: 570: 568: 567: 551: 549: 548: 543: 541: 540: 510:opportunity cost 499: 497: 496: 491: 489: 488: 472: 470: 469: 464: 462: 461: 445: 443: 442: 437: 435: 434: 418: 416: 415: 410: 408: 407: 351:consumer surplus 315:Martin Feldstein 285:Arnold Harberger 165:consumer surplus 161:producer surplus 142:marginal benefit 138:economic welfare 114: 107: 103: 100: 94: 92: 51: 27: 19: 1651: 1650: 1646: 1645: 1644: 1642: 1641: 1640: 1611: 1610: 1609: 1604: 1582: 1574: 1541: 1420: 1062:Deadweight loss 999:Consumer choice 977: 972: 935: 904: 878: 873: 867: 847: 844: 842:Further reading 839: 838: 828: 827: 814: 809: 805: 798: 785: 784: 780: 770: 768: 764: 763: 759: 725: 724: 720: 715: 683: 670: 652: 639: 613: 608: 607: 586: 581: 580: 559: 554: 553: 532: 527: 526: 480: 475: 474: 453: 448: 447: 426: 421: 420: 399: 394: 393: 386: 363:relative prices 347:Alfred Marshall 331: 319:economic trends 273: 256: 243: 226: 213: 195:, or a binding 134:deadweight loss 126: 115: 104: 98: 95: 52: 50: 40: 28: 17: 12: 11: 5: 1649: 1647: 1639: 1638: 1633: 1628: 1626:Price controls 1623: 1613: 1612: 1606: 1605: 1603: 1602: 1592: 1579: 1576: 1575: 1573: 1572: 1567: 1565:Macroeconomics 1562: 1561: 1560: 1549: 1547: 1543: 1542: 1540: 1539: 1534: 1529: 1524: 1519: 1514: 1509: 1504: 1499: 1494: 1489: 1484: 1479: 1474: 1469: 1464: 1459: 1454: 1449: 1444: 1439: 1434: 1428: 1426: 1422: 1421: 1419: 1418: 1413: 1412: 1411: 1406: 1396: 1391: 1390: 1389: 1380: 1366: 1361: 1356: 1351: 1342: 1337: 1332: 1327: 1322: 1317: 1312: 1307: 1302: 1301: 1300: 1295: 1286: 1281: 1276: 1271: 1266: 1264:Price controls 1256: 1251: 1246: 1245: 1244: 1239: 1234: 1229: 1228: 1227: 1222: 1212: 1207: 1206: 1205: 1200: 1185: 1183:Market failure 1180: 1175: 1170: 1165: 1160: 1155: 1150: 1149: 1148: 1143: 1133: 1128: 1123: 1118: 1117: 1116: 1106: 1105: 1104: 1099: 1094: 1089: 1079: 1074: 1069: 1064: 1059: 1054: 1053: 1052: 1047: 1042: 1037: 1036: 1035: 1025: 1020: 1010: 1001: 996: 991: 985: 983: 979: 978: 975:Microeconomics 973: 971: 970: 963: 956: 948: 942: 941: 934: 933:External links 931: 930: 929: 902: 891:(2): 167–188. 871: 865: 843: 840: 837: 836: 812: 803: 796: 778: 757: 717: 716: 714: 711: 710: 709: 704: 699: 694: 692:Land value tax 689: 682: 679: 675:social optimum 669: 666: 651: 648: 638: 635: 620: 616: 593: 589: 566: 562: 539: 535: 487: 483: 460: 456: 433: 429: 406: 402: 385: 382: 330: 327: 272: 269: 255: 252: 242: 239: 225: 222: 212: 209: 193:tax or subsidy 117: 116: 31: 29: 22: 15: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 1648: 1637: 1634: 1632: 1629: 1627: 1624: 1622: 1619: 1618: 1616: 1601: 1593: 1591: 1586: 1581: 1580: 1577: 1571: 1568: 1566: 1563: 1559: 1556: 1555: 1554: 1551: 1550: 1548: 1544: 1538: 1535: 1533: 1530: 1528: 1525: 1523: 1520: 1518: 1515: 1513: 1510: 1508: 1505: 1503: 1500: 1498: 1497:Institutional 1495: 1493: 1490: 1488: 1485: 1483: 1480: 1478: 1475: 1473: 1470: 1468: 1465: 1463: 1460: 1458: 1455: 1453: 1450: 1448: 1445: 1443: 1442:Computational 1440: 1438: 1435: 1433: 1430: 1429: 1427: 1423: 1417: 1414: 1410: 1407: 1405: 1402: 1401: 1400: 1397: 1395: 1392: 1388: 1387:Law of supply 1384: 1381: 1379: 1378:Law of demand 1375: 1372: 1371: 1370: 1367: 1365: 1364:Social choice 1362: 1360: 1357: 1355: 1352: 1350: 1349:Excess supply 1346: 1343: 1341: 1338: 1336: 1335:Risk aversion 1333: 1331: 1328: 1326: 1323: 1321: 1318: 1316: 1313: 1311: 1308: 1306: 1303: 1299: 1296: 1294: 1290: 1287: 1285: 1282: 1280: 1277: 1275: 1272: 1270: 1269:Price ceiling 1267: 1265: 1262: 1261: 1260: 1257: 1255: 1252: 1250: 1247: 1243: 1240: 1238: 1235: 1233: 1230: 1226: 1225:Complementary 1223: 1221: 1218: 1217: 1216: 1213: 1211: 1208: 1204: 1201: 1199: 1196: 1195: 1194: 1191: 1190: 1189: 1186: 1184: 1181: 1179: 1176: 1174: 1171: 1169: 1166: 1164: 1161: 1159: 1156: 1154: 1151: 1147: 1144: 1142: 1139: 1138: 1137: 1134: 1132: 1129: 1127: 1124: 1122: 1119: 1115: 1112: 1111: 1110: 1107: 1103: 1100: 1098: 1095: 1093: 1090: 1088: 1085: 1084: 1083: 1080: 1078: 1075: 1073: 1070: 1068: 1065: 1063: 1060: 1058: 1055: 1051: 1048: 1046: 1043: 1041: 1038: 1034: 1031: 1030: 1029: 1026: 1024: 1021: 1019: 1016: 1015: 1014: 1011: 1009: 1008:non-convexity 1005: 1002: 1000: 997: 995: 992: 990: 987: 986: 984: 980: 976: 969: 964: 962: 957: 955: 950: 949: 946: 940: 937: 936: 932: 925: 920: 916: 912: 908: 903: 898: 894: 890: 886: 885: 877: 872: 868: 862: 858: 854: 850: 849:Case, Karl E. 846: 845: 841: 832: 825: 823: 821: 819: 817: 813: 807: 804: 799: 793: 789: 782: 779: 767: 761: 758: 753: 749: 745: 741: 737: 733: 729: 722: 719: 712: 708: 705: 703: 700: 698: 695: 693: 690: 688: 685: 684: 680: 678: 676: 667: 665: 661: 658: 649: 647: 643: 636: 634: 618: 614: 591: 587: 564: 560: 537: 533: 522: 518: 514: 511: 506: 485: 481: 458: 454: 431: 427: 404: 400: 390: 383: 381: 379: 375: 370: 368: 364: 360: 356: 352: 348: 344: 340: 336: 328: 326: 324: 320: 316: 311: 307: 305: 300: 298: 297:externalities 294: 290: 286: 277: 268: 266: 262: 253: 251: 248: 240: 238: 235: 231: 223: 221: 219: 210: 208: 206: 202: 198: 197:price ceiling 194: 190: 186: 182: 178: 174: 166: 162: 158: 157:price ceiling 153: 149: 147: 146:marginal cost 143: 139: 135: 131: 124: 113: 110: 102: 91: 88: 84: 81: 77: 74: 70: 67: 63: 60: â€“  59: 55: 54:Find sources: 48: 44: 38: 37: 32:This article 30: 26: 21: 20: 1532:Optimization 1517:Mathematical 1477:Experimental 1472:Evolutionary 1457:Econometrics 1315:Public goods 1289:Price system 1284:Price signal 1198:Monopolistic 1067:Distribution 1061: 982:Major topics 917:(1): 63–73. 914: 910: 888: 882: 856: 853:Fair, Ray C. 830: 806: 787: 781: 771:February 11, 769:. Retrieved 760: 735: 731: 721: 671: 662: 657:more quickly 656: 653: 644: 640: 523: 519: 515: 507: 503: 371: 332: 312: 308: 301: 289:price floors 282: 257: 246: 244: 227: 214: 205:minimum wage 170: 133: 127: 105: 96: 86: 79: 72: 65: 53: 41:Please help 36:verification 33: 1482:Game theory 1447:Development 1394:Uncertainty 1274:Price floor 1254:Preferences 1193:Competition 1163:Information 1126:Externality 1109:Equilibrium 1050:Transaction 1028:Opportunity 989:Aggregation 697:Optimal tax 343:Marshallian 323:James Tobin 201:price floor 189:externality 1615:Categories 1512:Managerial 1432:Behavioral 1305:Production 1242:Oligopsony 1082:Elasticity 994:Budget set 713:References 707:Tax choice 341:) and the 339:John Hicks 203:such as a 69:newspapers 1553:Economics 1425:Subfields 1320:Rationing 1237:Oligopoly 1232:Monopsony 1220:Bilateral 1153:Household 1004:Convexity 752:150473969 130:economics 1631:Scarcity 1600:Category 1546:See also 1437:Business 1409:Marginal 1404:Expected 1345:Shortage 1340:Scarcity 1215:Monopoly 1121:Exchange 1033:Implicit 1023:Marginal 855:(1999). 681:See also 384:Taxation 335:Hicksian 234:monopoly 224:Monopoly 211:Examples 181:monopoly 99:May 2024 1558:Applied 1537:Welfare 1399:Utility 1359:Surplus 1298:Pricing 1210:Duopoly 1203:Perfect 1146:Service 1114:General 1018:Average 355:elastic 265:sin tax 241:Subsidy 83:scholar 1383:Supply 1374:Demand 1310:Profit 1178:Market 1040:Social 863:  794:  750:  365:has a 159:. The 85:  78:  71:  64:  56:  1502:Labor 1487:Green 1259:Price 1141:Goods 1131:Firms 879:(PDF) 748:S2CID 378:Pigou 345:(per 337:(per 304:wedge 90:JSTOR 76:books 1416:Wage 1325:Rent 1293:Free 1045:Sunk 1013:Cost 1006:and 861:ISBN 792:ISBN 773:2012 333:The 293:caps 247:more 191:, a 177:good 62:news 1507:Law 919:doi 893:doi 740:doi 606:to 473:to 254:Tax 199:or 128:In 45:by 1617:: 915:40 913:. 909:. 889:13 887:. 881:. 851:; 815:^ 746:. 736:12 734:. 730:. 299:. 291:, 207:. 132:, 1385:/ 1376:/ 1347:/ 1291:/ 967:e 960:t 953:v 927:. 921:: 901:. 899:. 895:: 869:. 800:. 775:. 754:. 742:: 619:t 615:Q 592:e 588:Q 565:p 561:P 538:c 534:P 500:. 486:t 482:Q 459:e 455:Q 432:p 428:P 405:c 401:P 125:. 112:) 106:( 101:) 97:( 87:· 80:· 73:· 66:· 39:.

Index


verification
improve this article
adding citations to reliable sources
"Deadweight loss"
news
newspapers
books
scholar
JSTOR
Learn how and when to remove this message
DWL (disambiguation)
economics
economic welfare
marginal benefit
marginal cost

price ceiling
producer surplus
consumer surplus
economic efficiency
good
monopoly
artificial scarcity
externality
tax or subsidy
price ceiling
price floor
minimum wage
economic equilibrium

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑