Knowledge (XXG)

Inferior good

Source 📝

415:. It is usual to attribute Giffen's observation to the fact that in Ireland during the 19th century there was a rise in the price of potatoes. The explanation follows that poor people were forced to reduce their consumption of meat and expensive items such as eggs. Potatoes, still being the cheapest food, meant that poor people started consuming more even though its price was rising. This phenomenon is often described as "Giffen's Paradox". However, it has been noticed that Giffen did not use potatoes as an example of Giffen goods. Moreover, potatoes were not Giffen Goods during the 361:
relatively cheaper in comparison to its substitutes. In other words, its substitutes become relatively costlier. Consumers would normally like to substitute cheaper goods for costlier ones. Thus, the demand for relatively cheaper substitute commodities increases. Compared to normal goods, a price decrease (or increase) would actually decrease (or increase) the consumption of an inferior good. This is only possible if negative income effect is strong or large enough to outweigh the substitution effect.
167: 334: 36: 317:, for example, generally conforms to the demand function of an inferior good in the Andean region where the crop originated. People of higher incomes and/or those who have migrated to coastal areas are more likely to prefer other staples such as rice or wheat products as they can afford them. However, in several countries of Asia, such as 369:
The income and substitution effects work in opposite directions for an inferior good. When an inferior good's price decreases, the income effect reduces the quantity consumed, whilst the substitution effect increases the amount consumed. In practice, it has been observed that the substitution effect
246:
establishments vastly represent a large percentage of goods referred to as "inferior". Cheaper cars are examples of the inferior goods. Consumers will generally prefer cheaper cars when their income is constricted. As a consumer's income increases, the demand for the cheap cars will decrease, while
351:
The income effect describes the relationship between an increase in real income and demand for a good. Inferior goods experience negative income effect, where its consumption decreases when a consumer's income increases. The increase in real income means consumers can afford a bundle of goods that
342:
The shift in consumer demand for an inferior good can be explained by two natural economic phenomena: The substitution effect and the income effect. These effects describe and validate the movement of the demand curve in (independent) response to increasing income and relative cost of other goods.
262:
travel, but is more time-consuming. When money is constricted, traveling by bus becomes more acceptable, but when money is more abundant than time, more rapid transport is preferred. In some countries with less developed or poorly maintained railways this is reversed: trains are slower and cheaper
226:
Inferiority, in this sense, is an observable fact relating to affordability rather than a statement about the quality of the good. As a rule, these goods are affordable and adequately fulfil their purpose, but as more costly substitutes that offer more utility become available, the use of the
360:
The substitution effect is the effect that a change in relative prices of substitute goods has on the quantity demanded. It due to a change in relative prices between two or more substitute goods. When the price of a commodity falls and prices of its substitutes remain unchanged, it becomes
301:
are additional examples of inferior goods. As incomes rise, one tends to purchase more expensive, appealing or nutritious foods. Likewise, goods and services used by poor people for which richer people have alternatives exemplify inferior goods. As a rule, used and obsolete goods (but not
149:
are those goods the demand for which falls with increase in income of the consumer. So, there is an inverse relationship between income of the consumer and the demand for inferior goods. There are many examples of inferior goods, including cheap cars, public transit options,
270:, are inferior goods. Such financial services are generally marketed to persons with low incomes. People with middle or higher incomes can typically use credit cards that have better terms of payment or bank loans for higher volumes and much lower rates of interest. 490: 133: 337:
An item such as non-branded grocery products are common inferior goods. There is no set criteria of what constitutes an inferior good, but economists refer to an inferior good as any item preferred less when disposable consumer income
227:
inferior goods diminishes. Direct relations can thus be drawn from inferior goods to socio-economic class. Those with constricted incomes tend to prefer inferior goods for the reason of the aforementioned observable inferiority.
136:
Good Y is a normal good since the amount purchased increases from Y1 to Y2 as the budget constraint shifts from BC1 to the higher income BC2. Good X is an inferior good since the amount bought decreases from X1 to X2 as income
370:
is usually larger than the income effect due to the small amount of gross income allocated by consumers on any given good, and thus the change in demand is usually insignificant in comparison to the substitution effect.
392:". Quite simply, when the price of a Giffen good increases, the demand for that good increases. This would have to be a particular good that is such a large proportion of a person or market's consumption that the 629: 722: 215:, inferior goods are goods whose demand decreases when consumer income rises (or demand increases when consumer income decreases). This behaviour is unlike the 656: 321:, potatoes are not an inferior good, but rather a relatively expensive source of calories and a high-prestige food, especially when eaten in the form of 923: 242:
There are many examples of inferior goods. A number of economists have suggested that shopping at large discount chains such as Walmart and
780: 755: 575: 517: 471: 119: 154:, and inexpensive food. The shift in consumer demand for an inferior good can be explained by two natural economic phenomena: the 563: 57: 53: 633: 100: 678: 72: 916: 590: 223:, for which the opposite is observed; normal goods are those goods for which the demand rises as consumer income rises. 664: 174: 79: 1149: 405: 46: 352:
give them higher utility. Inferior goods are unlikely to provide the latter, thus why its consumption decreases.
86: 1099: 959: 909: 416: 196: 68: 166: 964: 234:, the amount of a good bought can either increase, decrease, or stay the same when income increases. 692: 1104: 155: 693:"Substitution Effect and Income Effect: Definitions and Implications - Don't Quit Your Day Job..." 1026: 969: 872: 837: 829: 231: 310:
are inferior goods at the time even if they had earlier been normal goods or even luxury goods.
1046: 977: 864: 821: 786: 776: 751: 672: 584: 571: 523: 513: 467: 412: 216: 1036: 813: 541: 254:
service is also an example of an inferior good. This form of transportation is cheaper than
93: 1092: 1041: 1011: 997: 973: 944: 437: 420: 307: 278: 274: 605: 1075: 1021: 982: 267: 259: 190: 151: 657:"Sustainability of Potato Consumption in Developing Countries: The Case of Bangladesh" 1143: 1118: 1108: 1082: 987: 841: 442: 393: 389: 333: 1087: 1065: 1060: 1051: 992: 949: 855:
Dwyer, Gerald P.; Lindsay, Cotton M. (1984). "Robert Giffen and the Irish Potato".
397: 322: 183: 170: 1128: 1113: 1070: 1016: 486: 385: 379: 294: 243: 220: 178: 35: 1056: 1002: 318: 255: 17: 868: 825: 790: 527: 1123: 1007: 954: 286: 212: 142: 570:, Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458: Pearson Prentice Hall, p. 87, 132: 396:
of a price increase would produce, effectively, more demand. The observed
804:
Stigler, George J. (1947). "Notes on the History of the Giffen Paradox".
313:
Others are very inconsistent across geographic regions or cultures. The
247:
demand for costly cars will increase, so cheap cars are inferior goods.
876: 833: 303: 298: 432: 314: 817: 933: 332: 282: 165: 901: 423:
explanation of Giffen's Paradox was presented in terms of bread.
290: 905: 723:"Price Demand Relationship: Normal, Inferior and Giffen Goods" 251: 29: 632:. The Pew Charitable Trusts. 18 July 2012. Archived from 775:(Ninth ed.). New York: W. W. Norton. p. 104. 384:
A special type of inferior good may exist known as the
512:(Ninth ed.). New York: W. W. Norton. p. 96. 773:
Intermediate microeconomics : a modern approach
510:
Intermediate microeconomics : a modern approach
60:. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. 263:than buses, so rail travel is an inferior good. 917: 365:Overall change in demand for an inferior good 8: 667:, archived from the original on 8 April 2010 493:, South-Western Cengage Learning, 2012, p.70 924: 910: 902: 120:Learn how and when to remove this message 750:(18th ed.). Macmillan. p. 19. 306:) marketed to persons of low income as 131: 454: 670: 582: 266:Certain financial services, including 716: 714: 712: 7: 503: 501: 499: 58:adding citations to reliable sources 894:. New York: Macmillan. p. 132. 25: 696:DQYDJ – Don't Quit Your Day Job.. 411:Giffen goods were first noted by 230:Depending on consumer or market 34: 568:Economics: Principles in Action 542:"Economics A–Z: Inferior goods" 329:Income and substitution effects 45:needs additional citations for 566:; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003), 1: 466:(18th ed.). p. 11. 857:The American Economic Review 806:Journal of Political Economy 665:International Potato Center 630:"Payday Lending in America" 606:"Inferior Goods Definition" 388:, which would disobey the " 175:income elasticity of demand 1166: 655:Scott, G.J.; Bouis, H.E., 377: 940: 890:Marshall, Alfred (1949). 677:: CS1 maint: unfit URL ( 661:Program Report 1995–1996 589:: CS1 maint: location ( 998:(Post-)experience goods 892:Principles of Economics 771:Varian, Hal R. (2014). 508:Varian, Hal R. (2014). 491:Principles of Economics 273:Inexpensive foods like 158:and the income effect. 1109:(Non-)excludable goods 721:J.Singh (2014-06-17). 404:, indicating positive 339: 208: 138: 1105:(Non-)rivalrous goods 336: 169: 135: 965:Common-pool resource 727:Economics Discussion 54:improve this article 27:Concept in economics 1027:Global public goods 993:(Non-)durable goods 970:Complementary goods 356:Substitution effect 232:indifference curves 197:perfectly inelastic 156:substitution effect 1047:Intermediate goods 564:O'Sullivan, Arthur 487:Mankiw, N. Gregory 340: 209: 139: 1150:Goods (economics) 1137: 1136: 1037:Information goods 978:Independent goods 421:Alfred Marshall's 413:Sir Robert Giffen 325:by urban elites. 217:supply and demand 130: 129: 122: 104: 16:(Redirected from 1157: 1042:Intangible goods 1012:Positional goods 974:Substitute goods 945:Anti-rival goods 926: 919: 912: 903: 896: 895: 887: 881: 880: 852: 846: 845: 801: 795: 794: 768: 762: 761: 743: 737: 736: 734: 733: 718: 707: 706: 704: 703: 689: 683: 682: 676: 668: 652: 646: 645: 643: 641: 636:on 23 April 2016 626: 620: 619: 617: 616: 601: 595: 594: 588: 580: 560: 554: 553: 551: 549: 538: 532: 531: 505: 494: 484: 478: 477: 459: 207: 200: 194: 187: 125: 118: 114: 111: 105: 103: 62: 38: 30: 21: 1165: 1164: 1160: 1159: 1158: 1156: 1155: 1154: 1140: 1139: 1138: 1133: 1093:Household goods 1076:Necessity goods 983:Composite goods 936: 930: 900: 899: 889: 888: 884: 854: 853: 849: 803: 802: 798: 783: 770: 769: 765: 758: 745: 744: 740: 731: 729: 720: 719: 710: 701: 699: 691: 690: 686: 669: 654: 653: 649: 639: 637: 628: 627: 623: 614: 612: 603: 602: 598: 581: 578: 562: 561: 557: 547: 545: 544:. The Economist 540: 539: 535: 520: 507: 506: 497: 485: 481: 474: 461: 460: 456: 451: 438:Substitute good 429: 382: 376: 367: 358: 349: 331: 275:instant noodles 240: 202: 195: 191:necessity goods 189: 182: 164: 126: 115: 109: 106: 69:"Inferior good" 63: 61: 51: 39: 28: 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 1163: 1161: 1153: 1152: 1142: 1141: 1135: 1134: 1132: 1131: 1126: 1121: 1119:Superior goods 1116: 1111: 1102: 1097: 1096: 1095: 1085: 1083:Ordinary goods 1080: 1079: 1078: 1068: 1063: 1054: 1049: 1044: 1039: 1034: 1032:Inferior goods 1029: 1024: 1022:Global commons 1019: 1014: 1005: 1000: 995: 990: 988:Credence goods 985: 980: 967: 962: 957: 952: 947: 941: 938: 937: 931: 929: 928: 921: 914: 906: 898: 897: 882: 863:(1): 188–192. 847: 818:10.1086/256487 812:(2): 152–156. 796: 781: 763: 756: 738: 708: 684: 647: 621: 604:Kenton, Will. 596: 576: 555: 533: 518: 495: 479: 472: 453: 452: 450: 447: 446: 445: 440: 435: 428: 425: 378:Main article: 375: 372: 366: 363: 357: 354: 348: 345: 330: 327: 295:frozen dinners 289:, mass-market 268:payday lending 239: 236: 204:inferior goods 163: 160: 152:payday lending 147:inferior goods 128: 127: 42: 40: 33: 26: 24: 18:Inferior goods 14: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 1162: 1151: 1148: 1147: 1145: 1130: 1127: 1125: 1122: 1120: 1117: 1115: 1112: 1110: 1106: 1103: 1101: 1098: 1094: 1091: 1090: 1089: 1088:Private goods 1086: 1084: 1081: 1077: 1074: 1073: 1072: 1069: 1067: 1066:Neutral goods 1064: 1062: 1061:demerit goods 1058: 1055: 1053: 1050: 1048: 1045: 1043: 1040: 1038: 1035: 1033: 1030: 1028: 1025: 1023: 1020: 1018: 1015: 1013: 1009: 1006: 1004: 1001: 999: 996: 994: 991: 989: 986: 984: 981: 979: 975: 971: 968: 966: 963: 961: 958: 956: 953: 951: 950:Capital goods 948: 946: 943: 942: 939: 935: 927: 922: 920: 915: 913: 908: 907: 904: 893: 886: 883: 878: 874: 870: 866: 862: 858: 851: 848: 843: 839: 835: 831: 827: 823: 819: 815: 811: 807: 800: 797: 792: 788: 784: 782:9780393919677 778: 774: 767: 764: 759: 757:9789386811684 753: 749: 748:ISC Economics 742: 739: 728: 724: 717: 715: 713: 709: 697: 694: 688: 685: 680: 674: 666: 662: 658: 651: 648: 635: 631: 625: 622: 611: 607: 600: 597: 592: 586: 579: 577:0-13-063085-3 573: 569: 565: 559: 556: 543: 537: 534: 529: 525: 521: 519:9780393919677 515: 511: 504: 502: 500: 496: 492: 488: 483: 480: 475: 473:9789386811684 469: 465: 464:ISC Economics 458: 455: 448: 444: 443:Kuznets curve 441: 439: 436: 434: 431: 430: 426: 424: 422: 418: 414: 409: 407: 403: 399: 395: 394:income effect 391: 390:law of demand 387: 381: 373: 371: 364: 362: 355: 353: 347:Income effect 346: 344: 335: 328: 326: 324: 320: 316: 311: 309: 305: 300: 296: 292: 288: 284: 280: 276: 271: 269: 264: 261: 257: 253: 248: 245: 237: 235: 233: 228: 224: 222: 219:behaviour of 218: 214: 205: 198: 192: 185: 180: 176: 172: 171:Engels curves 168: 161: 159: 157: 153: 148: 144: 134: 124: 121: 113: 102: 99: 95: 92: 88: 85: 81: 78: 74: 71: –  70: 66: 65:Find sources: 59: 55: 49: 48: 43:This article 41: 37: 32: 31: 19: 1129:Veblen goods 1114:Search goods 1100:Public goods 1071:Normal goods 1052:Luxury goods 1031: 1017:Giffen goods 960:Common goods 891: 885: 860: 856: 850: 809: 805: 799: 772: 766: 747: 746:Sethi, D.K. 741: 730:. Retrieved 726: 700:. Retrieved 698:. 2010-04-23 695: 687: 660: 650: 638:. Retrieved 634:the original 624: 613:. Retrieved 610:Investopedia 609: 599: 567: 558: 546:. Retrieved 536: 509: 482: 463: 462:Sethi, D.K. 457: 419:in Ireland. 417:Great Famine 410: 401: 400:would slope 398:demand curve 383: 374:Giffen goods 368: 359: 350: 341: 323:French fries 312: 299:canned goods 272: 265: 249: 241: 229: 225: 221:normal goods 210: 203: 181:(comprising 179:normal goods 146: 140: 116: 110:October 2009 107: 97: 90: 83: 76: 64: 52:Please help 47:verification 44: 1057:Merit goods 1003:Final goods 386:Giffen good 380:Giffen good 250:Inter-city 244:rent-to-own 162:Description 1124:Used goods 1008:Free goods 955:Club goods 732:2021-04-23 702:2021-04-23 615:2021-04-23 449:References 406:elasticity 338:increases. 319:Bangladesh 193:(yellow)), 137:increases. 80:newspapers 932:Types of 869:0002-8282 842:153443575 826:0022-3808 791:879663971 548:17 August 528:879663971 308:closeouts 287:hamburger 213:economics 177:(YED) of 143:economics 1144:Category 673:citation 585:citation 427:See also 304:antiques 238:Examples 173:showing 877:1803318 834:1825304 640:28 July 279:bologna 199:(green) 94:scholar 875:  867:  840:  832:  824:  789:  779:  754:  574:  526:  516:  470:  433:Ersatz 402:upward 315:potato 297:, and 206:(blue) 184:luxury 96:  89:  82:  75:  67:  934:goods 873:JSTOR 838:S2CID 830:JSTOR 283:pizza 186:(red) 101:JSTOR 87:books 1107:and 1059:and 1010:vs. 976:vs. 972:vs. 865:ISSN 822:ISSN 787:OCLC 777:ISBN 752:ISBN 679:link 642:2015 591:link 572:ISBN 550:2016 524:OCLC 514:ISBN 468:ISBN 291:beer 260:rail 201:and 188:and 73:news 814:doi 258:or 256:air 252:bus 211:In 141:In 56:by 1146:: 871:. 861:74 859:. 836:. 828:. 820:. 810:55 808:. 785:. 725:. 711:^ 675:}} 671:{{ 663:, 659:, 608:. 587:}} 583:{{ 522:. 498:^ 489:, 408:. 293:, 285:, 281:, 277:, 145:, 925:e 918:t 911:v 879:. 844:. 816:: 793:. 760:. 735:. 705:. 681:) 644:. 618:. 593:) 552:. 530:. 476:. 123:) 117:( 112:) 108:( 98:· 91:· 84:· 77:· 50:. 20:)

Index

Inferior goods

verification
improve this article
adding citations to reliable sources
"Inferior good"
news
newspapers
books
scholar
JSTOR
Learn how and when to remove this message

economics
payday lending
substitution effect

Engels curves
income elasticity of demand
normal goods
luxury
necessity goods
perfectly inelastic
inferior goods
economics
supply and demand
normal goods
indifference curves
rent-to-own
bus

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.