Knowledge

Bureau-shaping model

Source đź“ť

184:
member; and that, within broad limits, officials’ influence on bureau policy is always correlated with rank and those nearest the top of bureaus are the most influential. Dunleavy therefore discards Niskanen’s assumption that a bureau’s behaviour will be wholly in line with the preferences of a single senior bureaucrat. In a bureau, where no individual has complete hegemony, budget maximisation is a collective, not an individual good. Rational utility maximising individuals will thus tend to favour strategies that directly advance their personal interests ahead of strategies that advance the collective good. The interaction of the maximising activities of individuals within a bureau will not necessarily lead to budget maximizing.
22: 146:
bodies by having policy determination and advice separated from the implementation of the legislated practices of government (as in the UK 'Next Steps' programme, Australian Department - Agency system) or off-loading functions to contractors and privatization. In the health and social work fields, officials will favour '
183:
Added to these are two assumptions which greatly weaken the budget-maximising conclusion. These are that a bureau’s aggregate policy behaviour is set by some combination of individual decisions made by its officials, although the actual combination that results may be an outcome desired by no bureau
145:
and doing interesting work, rather than to run large-budget agencies with many staff but also many risks and problems. For the same reasons, and to avoid risks, the bureau-shaping model also predicts that senior government bureaucrats will often favour either 'agencification' to other public sector
170:
public goods) but also x-inefficiency (by producing public goods inefficiently). Patrick Dunleavy, a British political scientist who set out to demolish the public choice arguments on bureaucracy, came instead in the end to develop a public choice model of bureaucratic behaviour which combines
165:
It was propounded in response to William Niskanen's harsh criticism of Public Bureaucracies in his Budget Maximising Model. The Niskanen model predicts that in representative democracies, public bureaucracies will not only generate allocative inefficiency (by
171:
elements of Peacock’s insight with the original American model. The Dunleavy (1985, p. 300) model of public bureaucracy is built on six basic assumptions. The first three are consistent with Niskanen’s model:
137:, but instead to shape their agency so as to maximize their personal utilities from their work. For instance, bureaucrats would prefer to work in small, 180:(iii) bureaucrats maximise their personal utilities (by satisfying "self-regarding, relatively hard-edged preferences") when making official decisions. 200:
Dollery, Brian and Hamburger, Peter, The Dunleavy and Niskanen Models of Bureaucracy: The Case of the Australian Federal Budget Sector 1982-92.
39: 177:(ii) governments largely depend on information from bureaus about the costs and value of producing within given ranges of output; and 105: 86: 58: 43: 65: 72: 216: 155: 130: 54: 32: 147: 142: 79: 151: 122: 210: 126: 21: 174:(i) bureau policies are set by bureaucrats interacting with the government; 134: 133:. It argues that rational officials will not want to maximize their 138: 15: 150:' and 'care in the community'. The model was developed by 162:(London: Pearson Education, 1991, reissued 2001). 46:. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. 8: 106:Learn how and when to remove this message 160:Democracy, Bureaucracy and Public Choice 193: 7: 44:adding citations to reliable sources 14: 20: 31:needs additional citations for 1: 141:agencies close to political 233: 156:London School of Economics 131:budget-maximization model 148:deinstitutionalization 129:and a response to the 55:"Bureau-shaping model" 40:improve this article 217:Political science 116: 115: 108: 90: 224: 201: 198: 152:Patrick Dunleavy 111: 104: 100: 97: 91: 89: 48: 24: 16: 232: 231: 227: 226: 225: 223: 222: 221: 207: 206: 205: 204: 199: 195: 190: 123:rational choice 112: 101: 95: 92: 49: 47: 37: 25: 12: 11: 5: 230: 228: 220: 219: 209: 208: 203: 202: 192: 191: 189: 186: 119:Bureau-shaping 114: 113: 28: 26: 19: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 229: 218: 215: 214: 212: 197: 194: 187: 185: 181: 178: 175: 172: 169: 168:oversupplying 163: 161: 157: 153: 149: 144: 143:power centres 140: 136: 132: 128: 124: 120: 110: 107: 99: 88: 85: 81: 78: 74: 71: 67: 64: 60: 57: â€“  56: 52: 51:Find sources: 45: 41: 35: 34: 29:This article 27: 23: 18: 17: 196: 182: 179: 176: 173: 167: 164: 159: 118: 117: 102: 96:January 2021 93: 83: 76: 69: 62: 50: 38:Please help 33:verification 30: 127:bureaucracy 188:References 66:newspapers 154:from the 125:model of 211:Category 135:budgets 80:scholar 82:  75:  68:  61:  53:  139:elite 121:is a 87:JSTOR 73:books 59:news 158:in 42:by 213:: 109:) 103:( 98:) 94:( 84:· 77:· 70:· 63:· 36:.

Index


verification
improve this article
adding citations to reliable sources
"Bureau-shaping model"
news
newspapers
books
scholar
JSTOR
Learn how and when to remove this message
rational choice
bureaucracy
budget-maximization model
budgets
elite
power centres
deinstitutionalization
Patrick Dunleavy
London School of Economics
Category
Political science

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑