Knowledge (XXG)

Incomplete markets

Source đź“ť

151:
idiosyncratic risks, each individual's consumption must fluctuate as much as anyone else's, and the relative position in terms wealth distribution of an individual should not vary much over time. The empirical evidence suggests otherwise. Further, the individual consumptions are not highly correlated with each other and wealth holdings are very volatile.
130:
between agents. For example, the realization of labor income for a given individual is private information and it cannot be known without cost by anyone else. If an insurance company cannot verify the individual's labor income, the former would always have the incentive to claim a low realization of
168:
to make it amenable to the powerful techniques of analysis developed for that framework. Second it is easy to compare model allocations with their empirical counterpart. Among the first papers using this approach, Diamond (1967) focused directly on the “realistic” market structure consisting of the
54:+ 1. If at each date-event there exists a complete set of such contracts, one for each contingency that can occur at the following date, individuals will trade these contracts in order to insure against future risks, targeting a desirable and budget feasible level of consumption in each state (i.e. 150:
Along with the Equity premium puzzle other counterfactual implications of the Complete Market model are related to the empirical observations concerning individuals’ consumption, wealth and market transactions. For example, in a Complete Market framework, given that agents can fully insure against
83:
environment. Their attitudes toward risk, the production possibility set, and the set of available trades determine the equilibrium quantities and prices of assets that are traded. In an "idealized" representation agents are assumed to have costless contractual enforcement and perfect knowledge of
172:
The other set of models explicitly account for the frictions that could prevent full insurance, but derive the optimal risk-sharing endogenously. This literature has focused on information frictions. Risk sharing in private information models with asset accumulation and enforcement frictions. The
376:
If the market is incomplete, meaning one or both of the securities are not available for trade, the two agents can't trade to hedge against a bad realization of nature and thus remain exposed to the possibility of the undesirable outcome of having zero wealth. In fact, with certainty, one of the
122:
In practice the idea of a state contingent security for every possible realization of nature seems unrealistic. For example, if the economy lacks the institutions to guarantee that the contracts are enforced, it is unlikely that agents will either sell or buy these securities.
189:
functions. There are two equally likely states of nature. If state 1 is realized, Robinson is endowed with 1 unit of wealth and Jane with 0. In state 2, Robinson gets 0 while Jane receives 1 unit of wealth. With Complete Markets there are two state contingent claims:
159:
In the economic and financial literature, a significant effort has been made in recent years to part from the setting of Complete Markets. Market incompleteness is modeled as an exogenous institutional structure or as an endogenous process.
380:
This example is an extreme case of market incompleteness. In practice, agents do have some type of savings or insurance instrument. The main point here is to illustrate the potential welfare losses that can arise if markets are incomplete.
173:
advantage of this approach is that market incompleteness and the available state contingent claims respond to the economic environment, which makes the model appealing for policy experiments since it is less vulnerable to the
62:
will not be possible. For this scenario, agents (homeowners, workers, firms, investors, etc.) will lack the instruments to insure against future risks such as employment status, health, labor income, prices, among others.
163:
In the first approach, the economic models take as given the institutions and arrangements observed in actual economies. This approach has two advantages. First the structure of the model is similar to that of the
84:
future states and their likelihood. With a complete set of state contingent claims (also known as Arrow–Debreu securities) agents can trade these securities to hedge against undesirable or bad outcomes.
253:
Before the realization of the uncertainty, the two agents can trade the state contingent securities. In equilibrium, the two Arrow-Debreu securities have the same price and the allocation is as follows:
367: 340: 310: 283: 247: 218: 91:
no longer holds. The competitive equilibrium in an Incomplete Market is generally constrained suboptimal. The notion of constrained suboptimality was formalized by
373:
The main outcome in this economy is that both Robinson and Jane will end up with 0.5 units of wealth independently of the state of nature that is realized.
111:
markets, markets remain incomplete. While several contingent claims are traded routinely against many states such as insurance policies,
147:
Mehra and Prescott (1985), where the Complete Market model failed to explain the historical high equity premium and low risk-free rate.
647: 473: 143:
is crucial to explain the counterfactual predictions of the standard Complete Market models. The most notable example is the
43:, this shortage of securities will likely restrict individuals from transferring the desired level of wealth among states. 665: 459:"Existence, regularity and constrained suboptimality of competitive allocations when the asset structure is incomplete" 50:
is a contract promising to deliver one unit of income in one of the possible contingencies which can occur at date
36: 600:
Diamond, P.A. (1967). "The Role of a Stock Market in a General Equilibrium Model with Technological Uncertainty".
458: 165: 32: 144: 127: 88: 55: 87:
When a market is incomplete, it typically fails to make the optimal allocation of assets. That is, the
395: 76: 140: 609: 582: 540: 439: 431: 72: 643: 469: 59: 578: 574: 532: 498: 423: 116: 112: 92: 345: 318: 288: 261: 225: 196: 631: 390: 40: 58:). In most set ups when these contracts are not available, optimal risk sharing between 174: 139:
Many authors have argued that modeling incomplete markets and other sorts of financial
414:
Arrow, K. (1964). "The Role of Securities in the Optimal Allocation of Risk Bearing".
659: 639: 502: 443: 586: 544: 17: 186: 185:
Suppose there is an economy with two agents (Robinson and Jane) with identical
80: 126:
Another common way to motivate the absence of state contingent securities is
536: 108: 104: 119:, among others, the set of outcomes is far greater than the set of claims. 466:
Uncertainty, information and communication: Essays in honor of K.J. Arrow
559: 613: 517: 435: 518:"Buffer-stock saving and the Life Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis" 427: 489:
Mehra, R.; Prescott, E.C. (1985). "The Equity Premium: A Puzzle".
638:, vol. I, Cambridge (Massachusetts), London (England): 560:"Quantitative Macroeconomics with Heterogeneous Households" 468:. Vol. 3. Cambridge University Press. pp. 65–95. 464:. In Hell, W.P.; Starr, R.M.; Starrett, D.A. (eds.). 348: 321: 291: 264: 228: 199: 361: 334: 304: 277: 241: 212: 457:Geanakoplos, J.D.; Polemarchakis, H.M. (1986). 135:Failure of the standard complete markets model 67:Markets, securities and market incompleteness 31:are markets in which there does not exist an 8: 377:agents will be 'rich' and the other 'poor'. 46:An Arrow security purchased or sold at date 558:Heathcote; Storessletten; Violante (2009). 181:Example of complete vs. incomplete markets 99:Possible reasons for market incompleteness 353: 347: 326: 320: 296: 290: 269: 263: 233: 227: 204: 198: 103:Despite the latest ongoing innovation in 249:pays 1 unit in state 2 and 0 in state 1. 579:10.1146/annurev.economics.050708.142922 406: 220:pays 1 unit in state 1 and 0 otherwise. 131:income and the market would collapse. 7: 25: 525:Quarterly Journal of Economics 155:Modeling market incompleteness 1: 516:Carroll, Christopher (1997). 636:Theory of Incomplete Markets 503:10.1016/0304-3932(85)90061-3 35:security for every possible 682: 567:Annual Review of Economics 416:Review of Economic Studies 95:and Polemarchakis (1986). 602:American Economic Review 169:stock and bond markets. 537:10.1162/003355397555109 630:Magill, Michael J.P.; 363: 336: 306: 279: 243: 214: 128:asymmetric information 364: 362:{\displaystyle q_{2}} 337: 335:{\displaystyle q_{1}} 307: 305:{\displaystyle q_{1}} 280: 278:{\displaystyle q_{2}} 258:Robinson buys 0.5 of 244: 242:{\displaystyle q_{2}} 215: 213:{\displaystyle q_{1}} 145:equity premium puzzle 89:First Welfare Theorem 77:intertemporal choices 56:consumption smoothing 666:Mathematical finance 396:Financial innovation 346: 319: 289: 262: 226: 197: 75:, each agent makes 39:. In contrast with 359: 332: 302: 275: 239: 210: 166:Arrow–Debreu model 73:competitive market 29:incomplete markets 342:and sells 0.5 of 315:Jane buys 0.5 of 285:and sells 0.5 of 18:Incomplete market 16:(Redirected from 673: 652: 632:Quinzii, Martine 618: 617: 597: 591: 590: 564: 555: 549: 548: 522: 513: 507: 506: 491:J. Monetary Econ 486: 480: 479: 463: 454: 448: 447: 411: 368: 366: 365: 360: 358: 357: 341: 339: 338: 333: 331: 330: 311: 309: 308: 303: 301: 300: 284: 282: 281: 276: 274: 273: 248: 246: 245: 240: 238: 237: 219: 217: 216: 211: 209: 208: 41:complete markets 21: 681: 680: 676: 675: 674: 672: 671: 670: 656: 655: 650: 629: 626: 621: 599: 598: 594: 562: 557: 556: 552: 520: 515: 514: 510: 488: 487: 483: 476: 461: 456: 455: 451: 428:10.2307/2296188 413: 412: 408: 404: 391:Complete market 387: 349: 344: 343: 322: 317: 316: 292: 287: 286: 265: 260: 259: 229: 224: 223: 200: 195: 194: 183: 157: 137: 101: 69: 37:state of nature 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 679: 677: 669: 668: 658: 657: 654: 653: 648: 625: 622: 620: 619: 608:(4): 759–776. 592: 550: 508: 481: 474: 449: 405: 403: 400: 399: 398: 393: 386: 383: 371: 370: 356: 352: 329: 325: 313: 299: 295: 272: 268: 251: 250: 236: 232: 221: 207: 203: 182: 179: 175:Lucas critique 156: 153: 136: 133: 100: 97: 68: 65: 27:In economics, 24: 14: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 678: 667: 664: 663: 661: 651: 649:0-262-13324-5 645: 641: 640:The MIT Press 637: 633: 628: 627: 623: 615: 611: 607: 603: 596: 593: 588: 584: 580: 576: 572: 568: 561: 554: 551: 546: 542: 538: 534: 530: 526: 519: 512: 509: 504: 500: 497:(2): 145–61. 496: 492: 485: 482: 477: 475:9780521327046 471: 467: 460: 453: 450: 445: 441: 437: 433: 429: 425: 421: 417: 410: 407: 401: 397: 394: 392: 389: 388: 384: 382: 378: 374: 354: 350: 327: 323: 314: 297: 293: 270: 266: 257: 256: 255: 234: 230: 222: 205: 201: 193: 192: 191: 188: 180: 178: 176: 170: 167: 161: 154: 152: 148: 146: 142: 134: 132: 129: 124: 120: 118: 114: 110: 106: 98: 96: 94: 90: 85: 82: 78: 74: 66: 64: 61: 57: 53: 49: 44: 42: 38: 34: 30: 19: 635: 605: 601: 595: 570: 566: 553: 528: 524: 511: 494: 490: 484: 465: 452: 422:(2): 91–96. 419: 415: 409: 379: 375: 372: 252: 184: 171: 162: 158: 149: 138: 125: 121: 115:, financial 102: 86: 70: 51: 47: 45: 33:Arrow–Debreu 28: 26: 573:: 319–354. 531:(1): 1–56. 187:log utility 93:Geanakoplos 624:Literature 402:References 81:stochastic 444:154606108 141:frictions 109:insurance 105:financial 660:Category 634:(1996), 587:13557384 545:14047708 385:See also 614:1815367 436:2296188 117:options 113:futures 646:  612:  585:  543:  472:  442:  434:  60:agents 610:JSTOR 583:S2CID 563:(PDF) 541:S2CID 521:(PDF) 462:(PDF) 440:S2CID 432:JSTOR 79:in a 71:In a 644:ISBN 470:ISBN 107:and 575:doi 533:doi 529:112 499:doi 424:doi 662:: 642:, 606:57 604:. 581:. 569:. 565:. 539:. 527:. 523:. 495:15 493:. 438:. 430:. 420:31 418:. 177:. 616:. 589:. 577:: 571:1 547:. 535:: 505:. 501:: 478:. 446:. 426:: 369:. 355:2 351:q 328:1 324:q 312:. 298:1 294:q 271:2 267:q 235:2 231:q 206:1 202:q 52:t 48:t 20:)

Index

Incomplete market
Arrow–Debreu
state of nature
complete markets
consumption smoothing
agents
competitive market
intertemporal choices
stochastic
First Welfare Theorem
Geanakoplos
financial
insurance
futures
options
asymmetric information
frictions
equity premium puzzle
Arrow–Debreu model
Lucas critique
log utility
Complete market
Financial innovation
doi
10.2307/2296188
JSTOR
2296188
S2CID
154606108
"Existence, regularity and constrained suboptimality of competitive allocations when the asset structure is incomplete"

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑