Knowledge (XXG)

Lewis–Mogridge position

Source 📝

316:". However, according to Downs, the link between average speeds on public transport and private transport applies only "to regions in which the vast majority of peak-hour commuting is done on rapid transit systems with separate rights of way. Central London is an example, since in 2001 around 85 percent of all morning peak-period commuters into that area used public transit (including 77 percent on separate rights of way) and only 11 percent used private cars. When peak-hour travel equilibrium has been reached between the subway system and the major commuting roads, then the travel time required for any given trip is roughly equal on both modes." 243: 66: 128: 25: 292:
Following the position, it is not generally concluded that new roads are never justified but that their development needs to consider the whole traffic system, which means understanding the movement of goods and people in detail as well as the motivation behind the movement.
307:
The position, however, is not confined to private transport. Mogridge, a British transport researcher, concluded also that all road investment in a congested urban area will have the effect of reducing the average speed of the transport system as a whole: road and
265:
consequently fills these roads. Speed gains from some new roads can disappear within months, if not weeks. Sometimes, new roads help to reduce traffic jams, but, in most cases, the congestion is only shifted to another junction.
516:
Mogridge, M. J. H., Holden, D. J., Bird, J. and Terzis, G. C. "The Downs–Thomson paradox and the transportation planning process". International Journal of Transportation Economics,
145: 38: 510: 352:, a corollary of which is that decreasing congestion may increase the distance people are willing to commute, thereby increasing the traffic burden 192: 164: 87: 387: 171: 483: 423: 229: 211: 109: 52: 44: 178: 149: 160: 339: 538: 300:
such as congested roads in cities and on motorways. It can also be used to explain the success of schemes such as the
80: 74: 313: 242: 138: 91: 301: 185: 533: 349: 329: 286: 254: 325: 500: 513:, Queueing Systems: Theory and Applications archive, Volume 49, Issue 3–4 (January 2005). 479: 429: 419: 344: 297: 309: 511:
The Downs–Thomson Paradox: Existence, Uniqueness and Stability of User Equilibria
366: 360: 355: 335: 282: 274: 527: 278: 507: 490:
Estimating the influence of public policy on road traffic levels in greater London
447: 328:, which states that adding a road to a road network can slow the traffic, and to 277:
in the transport literature, and was posited as the "Iron Law of Congestion" by
127: 433: 262: 501:
La conjecture de MJH Mogridge : test sur l’agglomération de Lyon
413: 285:(where the resource in question is traffic capacity), and relates to 289:(average commute times are similar in widely varying conditions). 241: 312:. The relationship and overall equilibria are also known as the " 415:
Still stuck in traffic: Coping with peak-hour traffic congestion
258: 121: 59: 18: 296:
The position is often used to understand problems caused by
476:
Travel in towns: jam yesterday, jam today and jam tomorrow?
503:(PDF), Cahiers Scientifiques du Transport (30), 1995. 257:, was formulated in 1990 and observes that as more 152:. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. 273:(Mogridge, 1990). It is generally referred to as 271:traffic expands to meet the available road space 388:"The Unstoppable Appeal of Highway Expansion" 8: 418:. Brookings Institution Press. p. 133. 369: – Roads that were closed or never used 53:Learn how and when to remove these messages 230:Learn how and when to remove this message 212:Learn how and when to remove this message 110:Learn how and when to remove this message 73:This article includes a list of general 379: 7: 150:adding citations to reliable sources 79:it lacks sufficient corresponding 14: 34:This article has multiple issues. 126: 64: 23: 520:, pp. 283–311, 1987. 506:Afimeimounga, H., Solomon, W., 478:Macmillan Press, London, 1990. 363:, a similar effect in computing 137:needs additional citations for 42:or discuss these issues on the 253:, named after David Lewis and 1: 492:. J. Transport Econ. Policy, 555: 448:"The Road Network Paradox" 281:. It is a special case of 161:"Lewis–Mogridge position" 474:Mogridge, Martin J. H., 302:London congestion charge 412:Downs, Anthony (2004). 251:Lewis–Mogridge position 94:more precise citations. 246: 16:Theory of road traffic 314:Downs–Thomson paradox 255:Martin J. H. Mogridge 245: 350:Marchetti's constant 330:Marchetti's constant 287:Marchetti's constant 146:improve this article 539:Transport economics 496:, pp. 155–168. 269:The position reads 247: 488:Lewis D. (1977), 345:John Glen Wardrop 298:private transport 240: 239: 232: 222: 221: 214: 196: 120: 119: 112: 57: 546: 462: 461: 459: 458: 444: 438: 437: 409: 403: 402: 400: 399: 384: 326:Braess's paradox 310:public transport 261:are built, more 235: 228: 217: 210: 206: 203: 197: 195: 154: 130: 122: 115: 108: 104: 101: 95: 90:this article by 81:inline citations 68: 67: 60: 49: 27: 26: 19: 554: 553: 549: 548: 547: 545: 544: 543: 524: 523: 471: 466: 465: 456: 454: 446: 445: 441: 426: 411: 410: 406: 397: 395: 386: 385: 381: 376: 322: 236: 225: 224: 223: 218: 207: 201: 198: 155: 153: 143: 131: 116: 105: 99: 96: 86:Please help to 85: 69: 65: 28: 24: 17: 12: 11: 5: 552: 550: 542: 541: 536: 534:Road transport 526: 525: 522: 521: 514: 504: 497: 486: 470: 467: 464: 463: 439: 424: 404: 378: 377: 375: 372: 371: 370: 367:Unused highway 364: 358: 356:Mohring effect 353: 347: 342: 340:rebound effect 336:Jevons paradox 333: 321: 318: 283:Jevons paradox 275:induced demand 238: 237: 220: 219: 134: 132: 125: 118: 117: 72: 70: 63: 58: 32: 31: 29: 22: 15: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 551: 540: 537: 535: 532: 531: 529: 519: 515: 512: 509: 505: 502: 499:Clément, L., 498: 495: 491: 487: 485: 484:0-333-53204-X 481: 477: 473: 472: 468: 453: 449: 443: 440: 435: 431: 427: 425:9780815796558 421: 417: 416: 408: 405: 393: 392:Bloomberg.com 389: 383: 380: 373: 368: 365: 362: 359: 357: 354: 351: 348: 346: 343: 341: 337: 334: 331: 327: 324: 323: 319: 317: 315: 311: 305: 303: 299: 294: 290: 288: 284: 280: 279:Anthony Downs 276: 272: 267: 264: 260: 256: 252: 244: 234: 231: 216: 213: 205: 202:February 2008 194: 191: 187: 184: 180: 177: 173: 170: 166: 163: –  162: 158: 157:Find sources: 151: 147: 141: 140: 135:This article 133: 129: 124: 123: 114: 111: 103: 93: 89: 83: 82: 76: 71: 62: 61: 56: 54: 47: 46: 41: 40: 35: 30: 21: 20: 517: 493: 489: 475: 455:. Retrieved 451: 442: 414: 407: 396:. Retrieved 394:. 2021-09-28 391: 382: 306: 295: 291: 270: 268: 250: 248: 226: 208: 199: 189: 182: 175: 168: 156: 144:Please help 139:verification 136: 106: 97: 78: 50: 43: 37: 36:Please help 33: 508:Ziedins, I. 361:Wirth's law 92:introducing 528:Categories 457:2017-04-28 452:Davros.org 398:2021-09-28 374:References 172:newspapers 100:April 2017 75:references 39:improve it 434:938122068 45:talk page 320:See also 469:Sources 263:traffic 186:scholar 88:improve 482:  432:  422:  188:  181:  174:  167:  159:  77:, but 259:roads 193:JSTOR 179:books 480:ISBN 430:OCLC 420:ISBN 338:and 249:The 165:news 148:by 530:: 518:14 494:11 450:. 428:. 390:. 304:. 48:. 460:. 436:. 401:. 332:. 233:) 227:( 215:) 209:( 204:) 200:( 190:· 183:· 176:· 169:· 142:. 113:) 107:( 102:) 98:( 84:. 55:) 51:(

Index

improve it
talk page
Learn how and when to remove these messages
references
inline citations
improve
introducing
Learn how and when to remove this message

verification
improve this article
adding citations to reliable sources
"Lewis–Mogridge position"
news
newspapers
books
scholar
JSTOR
Learn how and when to remove this message
Learn how and when to remove this message

Martin J. H. Mogridge
roads
traffic
induced demand
Anthony Downs
Jevons paradox
Marchetti's constant
private transport
London congestion charge

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.