Knowledge (XXG)

Social value orientations

Source 📝

93:, participants are asked to take the role of two criminals. In this situation, they are to pretend that they are a pair of criminals being interrogated by detectives in separate rooms. Both participants are being offered a deal and have two options. That is, the participant may remain silent or confess and implicate his or her partner. However, if both participants choose to remain silent, they will be set free. If both participants confess they will receive a moderate sentence. Conversely, if one participant remains silent while the other confesses, the person who confesses will receive a minimal sentence while the person who remained silent (and was implicated by their partner) will receive a maximum sentence. Thus, participants have to make the decision to cooperate with or compete with their partner. 181:: Competitors much like individualists strive to maximize their own outcomes, but in addition they seek to minimize others outcomes. disagreements and arguments are viewed as win-lose situations and competitors find satisfaction in forcing their ideas upon others. A competitor has the belief that each person should get the most they can in each situation and play to win every time. Those with competitive SVOs are more likely to find themselves in conflicts. Competitors cause cooperators to react with criticism to their abrasive styles. However, competitors rarely modify their behavior in response to these complaints because they are relatively unconcerned with maintaining interpersonal relations. 650:
between self and the other) is correlated with the degree of prosocial orientation. A functional magnetic resonance imaging study found that responses of Medial Prefrontal Cortex - an area that is typically associated with social cognition- mirrored preferences over competitive, individualistic and cooperative allocations. Similar findings in this or neighboring areas (ventromedial and dorsomedial prefrontal cortex) have been reported elsewhere.
175:: Members of this category are concerned only with their own outcomes. They make decisions based on what they think they will personally achieve, without concern for others' outcomes. They are focused only on their own outcomes and therefore do not get involved with other group members. They neither assist nor interfere. However their actions may indirectly impact other members of the group but such impact is not their goal. 595:
outcome for the self, a second option maximizes the sum of the outcomes for the self and the other (joint outcome), and the third option maximizes the relative gain (i.e. the difference between the outcome for the self and the outcome for the other). If a subject chooses an option indicating a particular SVO in at least six out of the nine items, the subject is categorized accordingly. That is, a subject is categorized as
209: 557:, i.e. a circle with a certain radius centered at the origin of the Cartesian plane. The vertical axis (y) measures the number of points or amount of money allocated to the other and the horizontal axis (x) measures the amount allocated to the self. Each pair of outcomes corresponds to two adjacent points on the circle. Adding up a subject's 24 choices yields a 28:) is a person's preference about how to allocate resources (e.g. money) between the self and another person. SVO corresponds to how much weight a person attaches to the welfare of others in relation to the own. Since people are assumed to vary in the weight they attach to other peoples' outcomes in relation to their own, SVO is an 883:. It is a challenge for future interdisciplinary research to combine the findings from different scientific disciplines and arrive at a unifying theory of SVO. Representing SVO in terms of a utility function and going beyond the construct's original conceptualization may facilitate the achievement of this ambitious goal. 97:
points or money. On the other hand, Option D is the competitive choice. If just one participants chooses option D, that participant will earn points or money while the other player will lose money. However, if both participant pick D, then both of them will lose money. In addition to displaying participant's
78:. As a simplifying assumption for analyzing strategic interactions, it was generally presumed that people only consider their own outcomes when making decisions in interdependent situations, rather than taking into account the interaction partners' outcomes as well. However, the study of human behavior in 649:
Some recent papers have explored whether Social Value Orientation is somehow reflected on human brain activity. The first functional magnetic resonance imaging study of Social Value Orientation revealed that response of the amygdala to economic inequity (i.e., absolute value of reward difference
561:
with a certain length and angle. The length of the vector indicates the consistency of a subject's choice behavior, while the angle indicates that subject's SVO. Subjects are then categorized into one out of eight SVO categories according to their SVO angle, given a sufficiently consistent choice
594:
as suggested by Messick and McClintock (1968). Concretely, the triple-dominance measure consists of nine items, each of which asks a subject to choose one out of three own-other-outcome allocations. The three options do have the same characteristics in each of the items. One option maximizes the
552:
The Ring measure was devised by Wim B. G. Liebrand in 1984 and is based on the geometric SVO framework proposed by Griesinger and Livingston in 1973. In the Ring measure, subjects are asked to choose between 24 pairs of options that allocate money to the subject and the "other". The 24 pairs of
96:
When used in the lab, the dynamics of this situation are stimulated as participants play for points or for money. Participants are given one of two choices, labeled option C or D. Option C would be the cooperative choice and if both participants choose to be cooperative then they will both earn
692:
Furthermore, it has been shown that individualism is prevalent among very young children, and that the frequency of expressions of prosocial and competitive SVOs increases with age. Among adults, it has been shown repeatedly that prosocial SVOs are most frequently observed (up to 60 percent),
104:
From behavior in strategic situations it is not possible, though, to infer peoples' motives, i.e. the joint outcome they would choose if they alone could determine it. The reason is that behavior in a strategic situation is always a function of both peoples' preferences about joint outcomes
619:
motivational groups. The instrument consists of 6 primary and 9 secondary items. In each item of the paper-based version of the Slider measure, a subject has to indicate her most preferred own-other outcome allocation out of nine options. From a subject's choices in the primary items, the
632:
along a continuum of own-other payoff allocations in the items, allowing for a very precise assessment of a person's SVO. The secondary items can be used for differentiating between the motivations to maximize the joint outcome and to minimize the difference in outcomes
717:. However, the general concept underlying SVO is inherently interdisciplinary, and has been studied under different names in a variety of different scientific fields; it is the concept of distributive preferences. Originally, the SVO construct as conceptualized by the 143:
To give an example, consider two options, A and B. If you choose option A, you will receive $ 100, and another (unknown) person will receive $ 10. If you choose option B, you will receive $ 85, and the other (unknown) person will also receive $ 85. This is a
187:: Cooperators tend to maximize their own outcomes as well as other's outcomes. They prefer strategies that generate win-win situations. When dealing with other people they believe that it is better if everyone comes out even in a situation. 231:, and represent own-other payoff allocation options as coordinates on a circle centered at the origin of the plane. If a person chooses a particular own-other outcome allocation on the ring, that person's SVO can be represented by the 112:
In an attempt to assess peoples' preferences over joint outcomes alone, disentangled from their beliefs about the other persons' behavior, David M. Messick and Charles G. McClintock in 1968 devised what has become known as the
874: 326:
would indicate a perfectly competitive (maximizing relative gain) SVO. This conceptualization indicates that SVO is a continuous construct, since there is an infinite number of possible SVOs, because angular degrees are
429: 193:: altruists are motivated to help other who are in need. Members of this category are low in self-interest. They willingly sacrifice their own outcomes in the hopes of helping others achieve gain. 562:
pattern. This measure allows for the detection of uncommon pathological SVOs, such as masochism, sadomasochism, or martyrdom, which would indicate that a subject attaches a negative weight (
148:. If a person chooses option B, we can infer that this person does not only consider the outcome for the self when making a decision, but also takes into account the outcome for the other. 879:
Several utility functions as representations of peoples' concerns for the welfare of others have been devised and used (for a very prominent example, see Fehr & Schmidt, 1999) in
140:. Since there is no other person making a decision that affects the joint outcome, there is no interdependence, and therefore a potential effect of beliefs on behavior is ruled out. 1123:
Haruno, M. & Frith, CD. (2010). Activity in the amygdala elicited by unfair divisions predicts social value orientation, Nature Neuroscience, Volume 13, 2010, Pages 160-161.
324: 294: 1018:
Au, W.T.; Kwong, J.Y.Y. (2004). "Measurement and effects of social-value orientation in social dilemmas". In Suleiman, R.; Budescu, D.; Fischer, I.; Messick, D. (eds.).
267: 693:
followed by individualistic SVOs (about 30-40 percent), and competitive SVOs (about 5-10 percent). Evidence also suggests that SVO is first and foremost determined by
486: 459: 205:) with which they could show that SVO is in principle not a categorical, but a continuous construct that allows for an infinite number of social value orientations. 580: 526: 506: 741:. For instance, a representation of SVO that includes the expression of a motivation to minimize differences between outcomes could be formalized as follows. 117:. Basically, any task where one decision maker can alone determine which one out of at least two own-other resource allocation options will be realized is a 1427: 746: 70:
The SVO construct has its history in the study of interdependent decision making, i.e. strategic interactions between two or more people. The advent of
334:
This advancement in the conceptualization of the SVO construct also clarified that SVO as originally conceptualized can be represented in terms of a
235:
of the line starting at the origin of the Cartesian plane and intersecting the coordinates of the respective chosen own-other outcome allocation.
1674: 1446: 1371: 343: 164:. There are four categories within SVO. Individualistic and competitive SVOs are proself while cooperative and altruistic SVOs are 1251:
D’Attoma, John W; Volintiru, Clara; Malézieux, Antoine (25 January 2020). "Gender, Social Value Orientation, and Tax Compliance".
904:
Forsyth, D.R. (2006). Conflict. In Forsyth, D. R., Group Dynamics (5th Ed.) (P. 378-407) Belmont: CA, Wadsworth, Cengage Learning
32:
variable. The general concept underlying SVO has become widely studied in a variety of different scientific disciplines, such as
625: 1499:
Offerman, T.; Sonnemans J.; Schram A. (1996). "Value Orientations, Expectations and Voluntary Contributions in Public Goods".
1644: 710: 17: 238:
If, for instance, a person would choose the option on the circle that maximizes the own outcome, this would refer to an
983:"'The effect of social motives, communication and group size on behaviour in an n-person multi stage mixed motive game" 638: 1192:
Kuss, Katarina; Falk, Armin; Trautner, Peter; Montag, Christian; Weber, Bernd; Fliessbach, Klaus (24 February 2015).
733:. The original SVO concept can be extended, though, by representing peoples' distributive preferences in terms of 1669: 951:
Griesinger, D. W.; Livingston, J. W. (1973). "Toward a model of interpersonal motivation in experimental games".
982: 681: 1614: 74:
in the 1940s provided a formal language for describing and analyzing situations of interdependence based on
29: 488:
is the outcome for the other, and the parameters indicate the weight a person attaches to the own outcome (
1609: 1194:"Neuronal correlates of social decision making are influenced by social value orientationâ€"an fMRI study" 1035:"Development of prosocial, individualistic, and competitive orientations: Theory and preliminary evidence" 729:. This particular motivation can also not be assessed with commonly used measures of SVO, except with the 726: 698: 536:
Several different measurement methods exist for assessing SVO. The basis for any of these measures is the
1534:
Radzicki, J. (1976). "Technique of conjoint measurement of subjective value of own and other's gains".
90: 83: 1135:"With you or against you: Social orientation dependent learning signals guide actions made for others" 1664: 1629: 722: 634: 328: 299: 1639: 1516: 1481: 1404: 1325: 272: 46: 917:
Messick, D. M.; McClintock, C. G. (1968). "Motivational Bases of Choice in Experimental Games".
245: 1428:"Commuting by car or public transportation? A social dilemma analysis of travel mode judgments" 1290: 1286: 1278: 1233: 1215: 1174: 1156: 1067: 464: 437: 136:, it is possible to infer that person's preferences over own-other resource allocations, i.e. 1577: 1569: 1508: 1473: 1442: 1394: 1386: 1352: 1317: 1268: 1260: 1223: 1205: 1164: 1146: 1106: 1057: 1049: 997: 960: 926: 734: 671: 616: 615:
The Slider measure assess SVO on a continuous scale, rather than categorizing subjects into
335: 1554: 1603: 296:
would indicate a perfectly cooperative (maximizing joint outcomes) SVO, while an angle of
228: 1343:
McClintock, C.G.; Allison, S.T. (1989). "Social value orientation and helping behavior".
1091: 160:. But when people are also concerned with others' gains and losses, they are said to be 1634: 1619: 1423: 1356: 1228: 1193: 1169: 1134: 666: 565: 511: 491: 197:
However, in 1973 Griesinger and Livingston provided a geometric framework of SVO (the
79: 75: 1658: 1485: 1329: 1151: 930: 694: 541: 122: 1408: 1649: 1372:"From games to giving: Social value orientation predicts donations to noble causes" 1305: 869:{\displaystyle U_{(\pi _{s},\pi _{o})}=a*\pi _{s}+b*\pi _{o}-c*|\pi _{s}-\pi _{o}|} 553:
outcomes correspond to equally spaced adjacent own-other-payoff allocations on an
1034: 1598: 686: 658:
SVO has been shown to be predictive of important behavioral variables, such as:
71: 1053: 109:
their beliefs about the intentions and behavior of their interaction partners.
1624: 1477: 1462:"The impact of social value orientations on negotiator cognition and behavior" 1390: 1306:"Social value orientation and cooperation in social dilemmas: A meta-analysis" 1110: 1321: 1282: 1219: 1210: 1160: 637:) among prosocial subjects. The SVO Slider Measure has been shown to be more 1573: 1264: 1001: 880: 738: 714: 641:
than previously used measures, and yields SVO scores on a continuous scale.
165: 126: 37: 33: 1447:
10.1002/(sici)1099-0992(199605)26:3<373::aid-ejsp760>3.3.co;2-t
1237: 1178: 86:, revealed that some people do in fact appear to have concerns for others. 1071: 964: 582:) to the outcome for the self given the utility function described above. 676: 1520: 1273: 1033:
Van Lange, P.A.M.; Otten, W.; De Bruin, E.M.N.; Joireman, J.A. (1997).
132:
By observing which own-other resource allocation a person chooses in a
41: 1581: 1399: 1062: 1512: 208: 1461: 232: 207: 1370:
Van Lange, P.A.M.; Bekkers, R.; Schuyt, T.; Van Vugt, M. (2007).
900: 898: 896: 219:
The basic idea was to represent outcomes for the self (on the
156:
When people seek to maximize their gains, they are said to be
129:, where it is often implemented as a constant-sum situation). 101:, it also displays the dynamics of a mixed-motives situation. 590:
The triple-dominance measure is directly based on the use of
424:{\displaystyle U_{(\pi _{s},\pi _{o})}=a*\pi _{s}+b*\pi _{o}} 713:, but has also been studied in other disciplines, such as 269:, indicating a perfectly individualistic SVO. An angle of 1090:
Murphy, R.O.; Ackermann, K.A.; Handgraaf, M.J.J. (2011).
544:. The most commonly used SVO measures are the following. 725:, which is a distributive preference heavily studied in 1022:. New York: Cambridge University Press. pp. 71–98. 1020:
Contemporary psychological research on social dilemmas
1133:
Christopoulos, George I.; King-Casas, Brooks (2015).
749: 568: 514: 494: 467: 440: 346: 302: 275: 248: 1555:"A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation" 868: 574: 520: 500: 480: 453: 423: 318: 288: 261: 1304:Balliet, D.; Parks, C.; Joireman, J. (2009). 1259:(3). Oxford University Press (OUP): 265–284. 1013: 1011: 8: 1085: 1083: 1081: 1042:Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 976: 974: 1460:De Dreu, C.K.W.; Van Lange, P.A.M. (1995). 912: 910: 44:under a multitude of different names (e.g. 1466:Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 1310:Group Processes & Intergroup Relations 946: 944: 942: 940: 1398: 1272: 1227: 1209: 1168: 1150: 1061: 919:Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 861: 855: 842: 833: 818: 799: 775: 762: 754: 748: 645:Neuroscience and Social Value Orientation 567: 513: 493: 472: 466: 445: 439: 415: 396: 372: 359: 351: 345: 310: 301: 280: 274: 253: 247: 1606:and his Social Values Orientation Theory 1099:Journal of Judgment and Decision Making 892: 701:plays a minor role in SVO development. 1435:European Journal of Social Psychology 990:European Journal of Social Psychology 7: 1345:Journal of Applied Social Psychology 1198:Frontiers in Behavioral Neuroscience 1092:"Measuring social value orientation" 721:did not include preferences such as 626:online version of the Slider measure 1379:Basic and Applied Social Psychology 1357:10.1111/j.1559-1816.1989.tb00060.x 624:can be computed. There is also an 14: 540:, i.e. a set of non-constant-sum 508:) and the outcome for the other ( 1553:Fehr, E.; Schmidt, K.M. (1999). 1152:10.1016/j.neuroimage.2014.09.011 709:The SVO construct is rooted in 1562:Quarterly Journal of Economics 862: 834: 781: 755: 378: 352: 1: 1536:Polish Psychological Bulletin 461:is the outcome for the self, 931:10.1016/0022-1031(68)90046-2 319:{\displaystyle -45^{\circ }} 223:) and for the other (on the 981:Liebrand, W. B. G. (1984). 289:{\displaystyle 45^{\circ }} 173:Individualistic orientation 121:(also often referred to as 52:other-regarding preferences 1691: 1675:Social psychology concepts 1204:. Frontiers Media SA: 40. 1054:10.1037/0022-3514.73.4.733 262:{\displaystyle 0^{\circ }} 1478:10.1177/01461672952111006 1426:; Meertens, R.M. (1996). 1391:10.1080/01973530701665223 1111:10.1017/S1930297500004204 682:proenvironmental behavior 538:decomposed game technique 115:decomposed game technique 99:social value orientations 1322:10.1177/1368430209105040 1211:10.3389/fnbeh.2015.00040 1145:. Elsevier BV: 326–335. 665:cooperative behavior in 586:Triple-Dominance Measure 481:{\displaystyle \pi _{o}} 454:{\displaystyle \pi _{s}} 138:social value orientation 82:situations, such as the 22:social value orientation 1615:Experimental psychology 1574:10.1162/003355399556151 1253:CESifo Economic Studies 1002:10.1002/ejsp.2420140302 185:Cooperative orientation 179:Competitive orientation 56:welfare tradeoff ratios 1610:Experimental economics 870: 727:experimental economics 699:genetic predisposition 576: 522: 502: 482: 455: 425: 338:of the following form 320: 290: 263: 216: 191:Altruistic orientation 1265:10.1093/cesifo/ifz016 965:10.1002/bs.3830180305 871: 628:, where subjects can 597:cooperative/prosocial 577: 523: 503: 483: 456: 426: 321: 291: 264: 211: 66:Historical background 30:individual difference 1630:Rokeach Value Survey 1501:The Economic Journal 747: 737:, as is standard in 705:Broader perspectives 687:negotiation behavior 566: 512: 492: 465: 438: 344: 300: 273: 246: 723:inequality aversion 635:inequality aversion 559:motivational vector 1640:Social preferences 953:Behavioral Science 866: 731:SVO Slider Measure 719:SVO ring framework 572: 518: 498: 478: 451: 421: 316: 286: 259: 217: 91:Prisoner's dilemma 84:prisoner's dilemma 47:social preferences 1645:Social psychology 1472:(11): 1178–1188. 1424:Van Lange, P.A.M. 735:utility functions 711:social psychology 677:donation behavior 575:{\displaystyle a} 521:{\displaystyle b} 501:{\displaystyle a} 152:Conceptualization 18:social psychology 1682: 1670:Moral psychology 1586: 1585: 1559: 1550: 1544: 1543: 1531: 1525: 1524: 1507:(437): 817–845. 1496: 1490: 1489: 1457: 1451: 1450: 1432: 1419: 1413: 1412: 1402: 1376: 1367: 1361: 1360: 1340: 1334: 1333: 1301: 1295: 1294: 1276: 1248: 1242: 1241: 1231: 1213: 1189: 1183: 1182: 1172: 1154: 1130: 1124: 1121: 1115: 1114: 1096: 1087: 1076: 1075: 1065: 1039: 1030: 1024: 1023: 1015: 1006: 1005: 987: 978: 969: 968: 948: 935: 934: 914: 905: 902: 875: 873: 872: 867: 865: 860: 859: 847: 846: 837: 823: 822: 804: 803: 785: 784: 780: 779: 767: 766: 672:helping behavior 592:decomposed games 581: 579: 578: 573: 527: 525: 524: 519: 507: 505: 504: 499: 487: 485: 484: 479: 477: 476: 460: 458: 457: 452: 450: 449: 430: 428: 427: 422: 420: 419: 401: 400: 382: 381: 377: 376: 364: 363: 336:utility function 325: 323: 322: 317: 315: 314: 295: 293: 292: 287: 285: 284: 268: 266: 265: 260: 258: 257: 125:, especially in 1690: 1689: 1685: 1684: 1683: 1681: 1680: 1679: 1655: 1654: 1604:Clyde Kluckhohn 1595: 1590: 1589: 1557: 1552: 1551: 1547: 1533: 1532: 1528: 1513:10.2307/2235360 1498: 1497: 1493: 1459: 1458: 1454: 1430: 1421: 1420: 1416: 1374: 1369: 1368: 1364: 1342: 1341: 1337: 1303: 1302: 1298: 1250: 1249: 1245: 1191: 1190: 1186: 1132: 1131: 1127: 1122: 1118: 1094: 1089: 1088: 1079: 1037: 1032: 1031: 1027: 1017: 1016: 1009: 985: 980: 979: 972: 950: 949: 938: 916: 915: 908: 903: 894: 889: 851: 838: 814: 795: 771: 758: 750: 745: 744: 707: 667:social dilemmas 662:fiscal behavior 656: 647: 613: 601:individualistic 588: 564: 563: 550: 534: 510: 509: 490: 489: 468: 463: 462: 441: 436: 435: 411: 392: 368: 355: 347: 342: 341: 306: 298: 297: 276: 271: 270: 249: 244: 243: 229:Cartesian plane 215:: The SVO ring 154: 146:decomposed game 134:decomposed game 119:decomposed game 68: 12: 11: 5: 1688: 1686: 1678: 1677: 1672: 1667: 1657: 1656: 1653: 1652: 1647: 1642: 1637: 1635:Social dilemma 1632: 1627: 1622: 1620:Human behavior 1617: 1612: 1607: 1601: 1594: 1591: 1588: 1587: 1568:(3): 817–868. 1545: 1526: 1491: 1452: 1441:(3): 373–395. 1422:Van Vugt, M.; 1414: 1385:(4): 375–384. 1362: 1351:(4): 353–362. 1335: 1316:(4): 533–547. 1296: 1243: 1184: 1125: 1116: 1105:(8): 771–781. 1077: 1048:(4): 733–746. 1025: 1007: 996:(3): 239–264. 970: 959:(3): 173–188. 936: 906: 891: 890: 888: 885: 864: 858: 854: 850: 845: 841: 836: 832: 829: 826: 821: 817: 813: 810: 807: 802: 798: 794: 791: 788: 783: 778: 774: 770: 765: 761: 757: 753: 706: 703: 690: 689: 684: 679: 674: 669: 663: 655: 654:Stylized facts 652: 646: 643: 612: 611:Slider Measure 609: 587: 584: 571: 549: 546: 542:dictator games 533: 530: 517: 497: 475: 471: 448: 444: 418: 414: 410: 407: 404: 399: 395: 391: 388: 385: 380: 375: 371: 367: 362: 358: 354: 350: 313: 309: 305: 283: 279: 256: 252: 195: 194: 188: 182: 176: 153: 150: 80:social dilemma 76:utility theory 67: 64: 60:social motives 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 1687: 1676: 1673: 1671: 1668: 1666: 1663: 1662: 1660: 1651: 1648: 1646: 1643: 1641: 1638: 1636: 1633: 1631: 1628: 1626: 1623: 1621: 1618: 1616: 1613: 1611: 1608: 1605: 1602: 1600: 1597: 1596: 1592: 1583: 1579: 1575: 1571: 1567: 1563: 1556: 1549: 1546: 1542:(3): 179–186. 1541: 1537: 1530: 1527: 1522: 1518: 1514: 1510: 1506: 1502: 1495: 1492: 1487: 1483: 1479: 1475: 1471: 1467: 1463: 1456: 1453: 1448: 1444: 1440: 1436: 1429: 1425: 1418: 1415: 1410: 1406: 1401: 1396: 1392: 1388: 1384: 1380: 1373: 1366: 1363: 1358: 1354: 1350: 1346: 1339: 1336: 1331: 1327: 1323: 1319: 1315: 1311: 1307: 1300: 1297: 1292: 1288: 1284: 1280: 1275: 1270: 1266: 1262: 1258: 1254: 1247: 1244: 1239: 1235: 1230: 1225: 1221: 1217: 1212: 1207: 1203: 1199: 1195: 1188: 1185: 1180: 1176: 1171: 1166: 1162: 1158: 1153: 1148: 1144: 1140: 1136: 1129: 1126: 1120: 1117: 1112: 1108: 1104: 1100: 1093: 1086: 1084: 1082: 1078: 1073: 1069: 1064: 1059: 1055: 1051: 1047: 1043: 1036: 1029: 1026: 1021: 1014: 1012: 1008: 1003: 999: 995: 991: 984: 977: 975: 971: 966: 962: 958: 954: 947: 945: 943: 941: 937: 932: 928: 924: 920: 913: 911: 907: 901: 899: 897: 893: 886: 884: 882: 877: 856: 852: 848: 843: 839: 830: 827: 824: 819: 815: 811: 808: 805: 800: 796: 792: 789: 786: 776: 772: 768: 763: 759: 751: 742: 740: 736: 732: 728: 724: 720: 716: 712: 704: 702: 700: 696: 695:socialization 688: 685: 683: 680: 678: 675: 673: 670: 668: 664: 661: 660: 659: 653: 651: 644: 642: 640: 636: 631: 627: 623: 618: 610: 608: 606: 602: 598: 593: 585: 583: 569: 560: 556: 547: 545: 543: 539: 531: 529: 515: 495: 473: 469: 446: 442: 432: 416: 412: 408: 405: 402: 397: 393: 389: 386: 383: 373: 369: 365: 360: 356: 348: 339: 337: 332: 330: 311: 307: 303: 281: 277: 254: 250: 241: 236: 234: 230: 226: 222: 214: 210: 206: 204: 200: 192: 189: 186: 183: 180: 177: 174: 171: 170: 169: 167: 163: 159: 151: 149: 147: 141: 139: 135: 130: 128: 124: 123:dictator game 120: 116: 110: 108: 102: 100: 94: 92: 87: 85: 81: 77: 73: 65: 63: 61: 57: 53: 49: 48: 43: 39: 35: 31: 27: 23: 19: 1650:Value system 1565: 1561: 1548: 1539: 1535: 1529: 1504: 1500: 1494: 1469: 1465: 1455: 1438: 1434: 1417: 1382: 1378: 1365: 1348: 1344: 1338: 1313: 1309: 1299: 1256: 1252: 1246: 1201: 1197: 1187: 1142: 1138: 1128: 1119: 1102: 1098: 1045: 1041: 1028: 1019: 993: 989: 956: 952: 922: 918: 878: 743: 730: 718: 708: 691: 657: 648: 629: 621: 614: 604: 600: 596: 591: 589: 558: 554: 551: 548:Ring Measure 537: 535: 433: 340: 333: 239: 237: 224: 220: 218: 212: 202: 198: 196: 190: 184: 178: 172: 161: 157: 155: 145: 142: 137: 133: 131: 118: 114: 111: 106: 103: 98: 95: 88: 69: 59: 55: 51: 45: 25: 21: 15: 1665:Game theory 1599:Cooperation 1274:10871/39813 697:, and that 605:competitive 532:Measurement 72:Game theory 1659:Categories 1625:Motivation 1582:10535/6398 1400:1871/17099 1139:NeuroImage 1063:1871/17714 887:References 329:continuous 1486:220683297 1330:141846910 1283:1610-241X 1220:1662-5153 1161:1053-8119 881:economics 853:π 849:− 840:π 831:∗ 825:− 816:π 812:∗ 797:π 793:∗ 773:π 760:π 739:economics 715:economics 622:SVO angle 470:π 443:π 413:π 409:∗ 394:π 390:∗ 370:π 357:π 312:∘ 304:− 282:∘ 255:∘ 240:SVO angle 166:prosocial 162:prosocial 127:economics 62:, etc.). 38:sociology 34:economics 1593:See also 1409:18146956 1238:25759643 1179:25224998 925:: 1–25. 639:reliable 555:SVO ring 213:Figure 1 203:Figure 1 199:SVO ring 1521:2235360 1291:3338701 1229:4338788 1170:4751040 1072:9325591 617:nominal 227:) on a 158:proself 89:In the 42:biology 1519:  1484:  1407:  1328:  1289:  1281:  1236:  1226:  1218:  1177:  1167:  1159:  1070:  434:where 225:y-axis 221:x-axis 201:, see 40:, and 1558:(PDF) 1517:JSTOR 1482:S2CID 1431:(PDF) 1405:S2CID 1375:(PDF) 1326:S2CID 1095:(PDF) 1038:(PDF) 986:(PDF) 630:slide 603:, or 233:angle 1287:SSRN 1279:ISSN 1234:PMID 1216:ISSN 1175:PMID 1157:ISSN 1068:PMID 1578:hdl 1570:doi 1566:114 1509:doi 1505:106 1474:doi 1443:doi 1395:hdl 1387:doi 1353:doi 1318:doi 1269:hdl 1261:doi 1224:PMC 1206:doi 1165:PMC 1147:doi 1143:104 1107:doi 1058:hdl 1050:doi 998:doi 961:doi 927:doi 528:). 242:of 107:and 26:SVO 16:In 1661:: 1576:. 1564:. 1560:. 1538:. 1515:. 1503:. 1480:. 1470:21 1468:. 1464:. 1439:26 1437:. 1433:. 1403:. 1393:. 1383:29 1381:. 1377:. 1349:19 1347:. 1324:. 1314:12 1312:. 1308:. 1285:. 1277:. 1267:. 1257:66 1255:. 1232:. 1222:. 1214:. 1200:. 1196:. 1173:. 1163:. 1155:. 1141:. 1137:. 1101:. 1097:. 1080:^ 1066:. 1056:. 1046:73 1044:. 1040:. 1010:^ 994:14 992:. 988:. 973:^ 957:18 955:. 939:^ 921:. 909:^ 895:^ 876:. 607:. 599:, 431:, 331:. 308:45 278:45 168:: 58:, 54:, 50:, 36:, 20:, 1584:. 1580:: 1572:: 1540:7 1523:. 1511:: 1488:. 1476:: 1449:. 1445:: 1411:. 1397:: 1389:: 1359:. 1355:: 1332:. 1320:: 1293:. 1271:: 1263:: 1240:. 1208:: 1202:9 1181:. 1149:: 1113:. 1109:: 1103:6 1074:. 1060:: 1052:: 1004:. 1000:: 967:. 963:: 933:. 929:: 923:4 863:| 857:o 844:s 835:| 828:c 820:o 809:b 806:+ 801:s 790:a 787:= 782:) 777:o 769:, 764:s 756:( 752:U 633:( 570:a 516:b 496:a 474:o 447:s 417:o 406:b 403:+ 398:s 387:a 384:= 379:) 374:o 366:, 361:s 353:( 349:U 251:0 24:(

Index

social psychology
individual difference
economics
sociology
biology
social preferences
Game theory
utility theory
social dilemma
prisoner's dilemma
Prisoner's dilemma
dictator game
economics
prosocial

Cartesian plane
angle
continuous
utility function
dictator games
nominal
online version of the Slider measure
inequality aversion
reliable
social dilemmas
helping behavior
donation behavior
proenvironmental behavior
negotiation behavior
socialization

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.