Knowledge (XXG)

O-ring theory of economic development

Source đź“ť

377:(2013) builds upon Kremer's O-ring theory to explain why differences in worker skills are associated with "massive" differences in international productivity levels despite causing only modest differences in wages within a country. For this purpose, he distinguishes between O-ring jobs—jobs featuring high strategic complementarities in terms of skill—and foolproof jobs—jobs characterized by diminishing returns to labor—and assumes both production technologies to be available to all countries. He then goes on to show that small international variations in average worker skill per country result in both large international and small intra-national income inequality. 175:
differs depending on interpretation. It could represent the probability of a worker successfully completing a task, the quality of task completion expressed as a percentage, or the quality of task completion with the condition of a margin of error that could reduce quality. Output then equals the
42:
The model argues that the O-ring development theory explains why rich countries produce more complicated products, have larger firms and much higher worker productivity than poor countries.
35:
in 1993, which proposes that tasks of production must be executed proficiently together in order for any of them to be of high value. The key feature of this model is positive
153: 271:
The important implication of this production function is positive assortative matching. This can be seen in a hypothetical four-person economy with two low skill workers (
512: 234: 214: 194: 173: 121: 101: 362:. As Kremer puts it, "If strategic complementarity is sufficiently strong, microeconomically identical nations or groups within nations could settle into 103:
tasks. Laborers can use a multitude of techniques of varying efficiency to carry out these tasks depending on their skill. Skill is denoted by
559: 494: 404: 569: 459: 46: 554: 337:
Wages will be more than proportionately higher in developed countries than would be assumed by measurements of skill levels;
574: 482: 584: 564: 359: 510:
Jones, Garett (2013). "The O-ring sector and the Foolproof sector: An explanation for skill externalities".
412: 520: 69: 286: 363: 28: 525: 237: 126: 579: 424: 334:
Workers performing the same task earn higher wages in a high-skill firm than in a low-skill firm;
77: 36: 347:
The effects of local bottlenecks are magnified which also reduces the expected returns to skill;
490: 455: 530: 447: 416: 65: 73: 322:
By this equation total product is maximized by pairing those with similar skill levels.
478: 399: 219: 199: 179: 158: 106: 86: 32: 24: 548: 341: 374: 451: 355: 534: 428: 350:
O-ring effects across firms can create national low-production traps.
236:. This scalar is positively correlated with the number of tasks. The 53: 420: 330:
There are several implications that can be derived from the model:
344:
investments in light of similar investments by those around them;
442:
Nafziger, E. W. (2005). "5 - Theories of Economic Development".
489:(Ninth ed.). Addison Wesley. pp. 166–167, 169–170. 216:
tasks together and scaling it by a firm specific constant,
39:, whereby people with similar skill levels work together. 76:
substitutes for one another, and there is a sufficient
402:(1993). "The O-Ring Theory of Economic Development". 222: 202: 182: 161: 129: 109: 89: 228: 208: 188: 167: 147: 115: 95: 64:The model assumes that firms are risk-neutral, 8: 473: 471: 394: 392: 390: 524: 366:with different levels of human capital". 221: 201: 181: 160: 128: 108: 88: 52:, a catastrophe caused by the failure of 386: 68:are competitive, workers supply labor 21:O-ring theory of economic development 7: 45:The name is a reference to the 1986 14: 360:international economic disparity 83:Production is broken down into 285:). This equation dictates the 278:) and two high skill workers ( 1: 148:{\displaystyle 0\leq q\leq 1} 16:Model of economic development 452:10.1017/CBO9780511805615.006 601: 535:10.1016/j.jebo.2012.10.014 560:Human resource management 354:This model helps explain 570:Organizational structure 413:Oxford University Press 513:J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 340:Workers will consider 230: 210: 196:values of each of the 190: 169: 149: 117: 97: 555:Development economics 287:productive efficiency 231: 211: 191: 170: 150: 118: 98: 575:Production economics 487:Economic Development 446:. pp. 123–164. 444:Economic Development 220: 200: 180: 159: 127: 107: 87: 37:assortative matching 29:economic development 289:of skill matching: 238:production function 226: 206: 186: 165: 145: 113: 93: 585:Economic theories 483:Smith, Stephen C. 229:{\displaystyle B} 209:{\displaystyle n} 189:{\displaystyle q} 168:{\displaystyle q} 155:. The concept of 116:{\displaystyle q} 96:{\displaystyle n} 592: 565:Labour economics 539: 538: 528: 507: 501: 500: 475: 466: 465: 439: 433: 432: 396: 318: 284: 277: 267: 235: 233: 232: 227: 215: 213: 212: 207: 195: 193: 192: 187: 174: 172: 171: 166: 154: 152: 151: 146: 122: 120: 119: 114: 102: 100: 99: 94: 50:shuttle disaster 600: 599: 595: 594: 593: 591: 590: 589: 545: 544: 543: 542: 526:10.1.1.733.8351 509: 508: 504: 497: 479:Todaro, Michael 477: 476: 469: 462: 441: 440: 436: 421:10.2307/2118400 400:Kremer, Michael 398: 397: 388: 383: 372: 328: 316: 312: 305: 298: 293: 283: 279: 276: 272: 265: 261: 254: 250: 244: 218: 217: 198: 197: 178: 177: 176:product of the 157: 156: 125: 124: 105: 104: 85: 84: 78:complementarity 62: 31:put forward by 17: 12: 11: 5: 598: 596: 588: 587: 582: 577: 572: 567: 562: 557: 547: 546: 541: 540: 502: 496:978-1408284476 495: 467: 460: 434: 385: 384: 382: 379: 371: 368: 352: 351: 348: 345: 338: 335: 327: 324: 320: 319: 314: 310: 303: 296: 281: 274: 269: 268: 263: 259: 252: 248: 225: 205: 185: 164: 144: 141: 138: 135: 132: 112: 92: 72:, workers are 61: 58: 33:Michael Kremer 15: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 597: 586: 583: 581: 578: 576: 573: 571: 568: 566: 563: 561: 558: 556: 553: 552: 550: 536: 532: 527: 522: 518: 515: 514: 506: 503: 498: 492: 488: 484: 480: 474: 472: 468: 463: 461:9780511805615 457: 453: 449: 445: 438: 435: 430: 426: 422: 418: 414: 410: 407: 406: 401: 395: 393: 391: 387: 380: 378: 376: 369: 367: 365: 361: 357: 349: 346: 343: 342:human capital 339: 336: 333: 332: 331: 325: 323: 317: 306: 299: 292: 291: 290: 288: 266: 255: 243: 242: 241: 239: 223: 203: 183: 162: 142: 139: 136: 133: 130: 110: 90: 81: 79: 75: 71: 70:inelastically 67: 66:labor markets 59: 57: 55: 51: 49: 43: 40: 38: 34: 30: 26: 22: 516: 511: 505: 486: 443: 437: 408: 403: 375:Garett Jones 373: 353: 329: 321: 308: 301: 294: 270: 257: 246: 82: 63: 47: 44: 41: 20: 18: 415:: 551–575. 405:Q. J. Econ. 356:brain drain 326:Conclusions 549:Categories 381:References 370:Extensions 364:equilibria 80:of tasks. 48:Challenger 580:Workplace 521:CiteSeerX 140:≤ 134:≤ 74:imperfect 519:: 1–10. 485:(2011). 123:, where 429:2118400 54:O-rings 523:  493:  458:  427:  425:JSTOR 411:(3). 60:Model 25:model 23:is a 491:ISBN 456:ISBN 358:and 256:) = 240:is: 19:The 531:doi 448:doi 417:doi 409:108 307:≥ 2 251:, q 27:of 551:: 529:. 517:85 481:; 470:^ 454:. 423:. 389:^ 300:+ 258:Bq 245:F( 56:. 537:. 533:: 499:. 464:. 450:: 431:. 419:: 315:L 313:q 311:H 309:q 304:L 302:q 297:H 295:q 282:H 280:q 275:L 273:q 264:j 262:q 260:i 253:j 249:i 247:q 224:B 204:n 184:q 163:q 143:1 137:q 131:0 111:q 91:n

Index

model
economic development
Michael Kremer
assortative matching
Challenger shuttle disaster
O-rings
labor markets
inelastically
imperfect
complementarity
production function
productive efficiency
human capital
brain drain
international economic disparity
equilibria
Garett Jones



Kremer, Michael
Q. J. Econ.
Oxford University Press
doi
10.2307/2118400
JSTOR
2118400
doi
10.1017/CBO9780511805615.006
ISBN

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑