Knowledge (XXG)

Ricardo–Viner model

Source 📝

181:; holding all the other factors of production constant, an increase in labor will mean less of the other factor per worker and in turn each additional worker will add less production than the last. Additionally, the specific factors model demonstrates that trade generally benefits the factors of production specific to the export sector of a country while hurting the factor specific to the import-competing sector as the relative prices of the factors adjust to the country's 38: 158:, the specific factors model allows for the existence of factors of production besides labor. In other words, labor is mobile, while the two other factors of production are immobile (sector specific) as opposed to the Ricardian model where labor is immobile internationally, but mobile between two sectors of an economy. 188:
However, when the Ricardian–Viner model is treated as dynamic, the sector-specific factors of production can become mobile over time. Under these circumstances, the Ricardian–Viner model exhibits a Heckscher–Ohlin equilibrium in the long run similar to that of the
55: 177:(labor) can be used in the production of both goods and can therefore move between sectors. In the use of labor, there will normally be diminishing 262:
R. Krugman, Paul, Obstfeld, Maurice, J.Melitz, Marc (2015). " International Economics". Theory and policy. Pearson Education Limited. pp:83-97.
102: 369: 74: 296: 121: 81: 267: 88: 59: 190: 166:
The economy in this model consists of two countries, two goods and three factors of production. The two countries can only
70: 143: 194: 48: 95: 236: 174: 151: 320:
Neary, J. Peter (1978). "Short-Run Capital Specificity and the Pure Theory of International Trade".
345: 337: 302: 292: 263: 182: 288: 281: 329: 222: 178: 150:'s interest in explaining the migration of workers from the rural to urban areas after the 249: 155: 363: 17: 147: 37: 287:. Obstfeld, Maurice. (4th ed.). Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley. pp.  341: 306: 349: 215: 193:. In this sense, the model can be seen as a short-run version of the 333: 227: 167: 31: 62:. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. 280: 214:Leamer, Edward; Levinsohn, James (November 1994). 283:International economics : theory and policy 142:, is an extension of the Ricardo model used in 8: 27:Economic model in international trade theory 216:"International Trade Theory: The Evidence" 226: 122:Learn how and when to remove this message 206: 245: 234: 7: 60:adding citations to reliable sources 170:goods, not factors of production. 25: 36: 47:needs additional citations for 1: 386: 370:International trade theory 197:of comparative advantage. 144:international trade theory 279:Krugman, Paul R. (1997). 191:Stolper–Samuelson theorem 162:Assumptions of the model 244:Cite journal requires 140:specific factors model 195:Heckscher–Ohlin model 173:Here only the mobile 152:Industrial revolution 71:"Ricardo–Viner model" 322:The Economic Journal 138:, also known as the 56:improve this article 136:Ricardo–Viner model 18:Ricardo-Viner model 221:. Cambridge, MA. 183:budget constraint 175:production factor 132: 131: 124: 106: 16:(Redirected from 377: 354: 353: 328:(351): 488–510. 317: 311: 310: 286: 276: 270: 260: 254: 253: 247: 242: 240: 232: 230: 220: 211: 179:returns to scale 146:. It was due to 127: 120: 116: 113: 107: 105: 64: 40: 32: 21: 385: 384: 380: 379: 378: 376: 375: 374: 360: 359: 358: 357: 334:10.2307/2232049 319: 318: 314: 299: 278: 277: 273: 261: 257: 243: 233: 218: 213: 212: 208: 203: 164: 156:Ricardian model 128: 117: 111: 108: 65: 63: 53: 41: 28: 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 383: 381: 373: 372: 362: 361: 356: 355: 312: 298:978-0673524973 297: 271: 255: 246:|journal= 205: 204: 202: 199: 163: 160: 130: 129: 44: 42: 35: 26: 24: 14: 13: 10: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 382: 371: 368: 367: 365: 351: 347: 343: 339: 335: 331: 327: 323: 316: 313: 308: 304: 300: 294: 290: 285: 284: 275: 272: 269: 265: 259: 256: 251: 238: 229: 228:10.3386/w4940 224: 217: 210: 207: 200: 198: 196: 192: 186: 184: 180: 176: 171: 169: 161: 159: 157: 154:. Unlike the 153: 149: 145: 141: 137: 126: 123: 115: 104: 101: 97: 94: 90: 87: 83: 80: 76: 73: –  72: 68: 67:Find sources: 61: 57: 51: 50: 45:This article 43: 39: 34: 33: 30: 19: 325: 321: 315: 282: 274: 258: 237:cite journal 209: 187: 172: 165: 139: 135: 133: 118: 109: 99: 92: 85: 78: 66: 54:Please help 49:verification 46: 29: 148:Jacob Viner 268:1292019557 201:References 82:newspapers 342:0013-0133 112:June 2016 364:Category 307:34886635 350:2232049 96:scholar 348:  340:  305:  295:  266:  98:  91:  84:  77:  69:  346:JSTOR 289:40–60 219:(PDF) 168:trade 103:JSTOR 89:books 338:ISSN 303:OCLC 293:ISBN 264:ISBN 250:help 134:The 75:news 330:doi 223:doi 58:by 366:: 344:. 336:. 326:88 324:. 301:. 291:. 241:: 239:}} 235:{{ 185:. 352:. 332:: 309:. 252:) 248:( 231:. 225:: 125:) 119:( 114:) 110:( 100:· 93:· 86:· 79:· 52:. 20:)

Index

Ricardo-Viner model

verification
improve this article
adding citations to reliable sources
"Ricardo–Viner model"
news
newspapers
books
scholar
JSTOR
Learn how and when to remove this message
international trade theory
Jacob Viner
Industrial revolution
Ricardian model
trade
production factor
returns to scale
budget constraint
Stolper–Samuelson theorem
Heckscher–Ohlin model
"International Trade Theory: The Evidence"
doi
10.3386/w4940
cite journal
help
ISBN
1292019557
International economics : theory and policy

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.